Open access peer-reviewed chapter

Saving Time in Portfolio Optimization on Financial Markets

Written By

Todor Atanasov Stoilov, Krasimira Petrova Stoilova and Miroslav Dimitrov Vladimirov

Submitted: 07 June 2019 Reviewed: 02 August 2019 Published: 14 September 2019

DOI: 10.5772/intechopen.88985

From the Edited Volume

Application of Decision Science in Business and Management

Edited by Fausto Pedro García Márquez

Chapter metrics overview

1,072 Chapter Downloads

View Full Metrics

Abstract

The time management is important part for tasks in real-time operation of systems, automation systems, optimization in complex system, taking explicit consideration in time constraints, scheduling of tasks and operations, making with incomplete data, and time management in different practical cases. The limit in time for taking appropriate decisions for management and control is a strong constraint for the implementation of autonomic functionalities as self-configuration, self-optimization, self-healing, self-protection in computer systems, transportation systems, and distributed systems. Time is an important and expensive resource. The time management in financial domain is a prerequisite for high competitiveness and an increase in the quality of the investment activities. It is the popular phrase that time is money, and particularly, the portfolio optimization targets its implementation in real cases. This research targets the identification of portfolio parameters, which are strongly influenced by time. We restrict our considerations only on portfolio optimization task, and we identify cases, which are strongly influenced by time constraints. Thus, the portfolio optimization problem is discussed on position how the time can influence the portfolio characteristics and solutions. This chapter starts with the description of the object portfolio management, which provides the cases where time in explicit way influences the portfolio problem.

Keywords

  • data driven analysis
  • real-time portfolio optimization
  • decision making
  • automation in information systems

1. Introduction

The time management is important part for tasks in real time operation of systems, automation systems, optimization in complex system, taking explicit consideration in time constraints, scheduling of tasks and operations, making with incomplete data, time management in different practical cases. The limits in time for taking appropriate decisions for management and control is a strong constraints for the implementation of autonomic functionalities as self-configuration, self-optimization, self-healing, self-protection in computer systems, transportation systems, distributed systems. Time is an important and expensive resource.

The time management in financial domain is a prerequisite for high competitiveness and increase of the quality of the investment activities. It is the popular phrase that “time is money” and particularly the portfolio optimization targets its implementation in real cases. This research targets the identification of portfolio parameters, which are strongly influenced by time. We restrict our considerations only on portfolio optimization task and we identify cases, which are strongly influenced by time constraints. Thus, the portfolio optimization problem is discussed on position how the time can influence the portfolio characteristics and solutions. This chapter starts with description of the object “portfolio management” which provides the cases where time in explicit way influences the portfolio problem.

Advertisement

2. Portfolio optimization problem

The task, which is resolved by the portfolio optimization of financial resources, is related with maximization of the return and simultaneously minimization of the investment risk. The portfolio optimization can be applied also to assets, which belong to the stock markets, because the same valued characteristics are used for portfolio optimization. The goal of the portfolio problem is to share the amount of investments among a set of securities, which are chosen to enter into the portfolio. The portfolio goal is to allocate in optimal manner the parts of the investment for buying securities. The time management problem initially arises with its complexity on the stage of the portfolio definition. The investment procedure has to be implemented at time t0 (now). The assets’ characteristics can be evaluated for this time moment t0, Figure 1.

Figure 1.

Time schedule of the portfolio investment.

The portfolio management insists to make decision for buying (or selling) assets at the current time t0. Then after a period of time t > 0 at time moment T = t 0 + t the investor has to sell (or buy) the assets from the portfolio and must receive positive return

Return T = Receipt T Expenditure t 0 Expenditure t 0 E1

The value of the Receipt is defined in the future time T and the Expenditure—on the current time t0. The portfolio problem arises according to the difference of the time moment t 0 < T . The investment decisions are based on the assets’ characteristics for the moment t0, A(t0). But in time T these characteristics will be A(T) and in common case they will differ in values A t 0 A T . These differences strongly influence the portfolio return at time T. In general, the assets’ characteristics are the return and risk, A i t 0 = A i Return i t 0 Risk i t 0 , i = 1 , , N , N is the types of assets in the portfolio which are evaluated for the current time t0. But the portfolio return is evaluated at the end of the investment period T. Respectively, the assets’ characteristics at time T are different A i T = A i Return i T Risk i T , i = 1 , N . Hence, the final portfolio returns from (1) becomes

Portfolio _ Return = Return A T Expenditures A ( t 0 ] Expenditures A ( t 0 ] E2

Following (2) for the implementation of the portfolio investment, the investor has:

  • to choose the types and number of assets N, which will participate in the portfolio;

  • to assess the assets’ characteristics Riski(t0) and Returni(t0), i = 1,…, N at the current time t0;

  • to choose the duration ∆t of the investment, which defines the final investment time T;

  • to forecast the assets’ characteristics Riski(T) and Returni(T), i = 1,…, N for the end of the investment period T;

  • to define and solve the portfolio optimization problem which will give the relative weights wi, i = 1,…,N of the investment, allocated for buying (selling) asset i. The relative values of weights introduce the analytical constraint

i = 1 N w i = 1 E3

and wi are the solutions of the portfolio optimization problem. To move ahead about the time management problem and to recommend relations between t0, ∆t and T there is a need to analyze the character of the portfolio optimization problem.

Advertisement

3. Modern Portfolio Theory

The Modern Portfolio Theory (MPT) was quantitatively introduced from Markowitz, with his seminal work [1]. The problems, introduced for the portfolio optimization are defined with two formal descriptions:

  • maximization of portfolio Return by finding optimal values of the assets’ weights wi, i = 1,…,N, satisfying constraints about portfolio Risk to stay below a predefined value

max w E T w w T Σw σ max 2 E4

  • and/or minimization of portfolio Risk by finding optimal assets’ weights wi, i = 1,…,N, satisfying constraints about the portfolio Return to stay over a predefined value

min w w T Σw E T w E min . E5

The notations used concern

Ei—the mean return of asset i = 1,…,N, ET = (E1, …, EN),

 − is the covariance matrix of the assets’ returns, square symmetrical N × N matrix,

σ max 2 —the maximal portfolio risk, which the investor can afford for problem (4),

Emin—the minimal portfolio return which the investor expects from the investment,

wT = (w1, …, wN)—a vector of relative weights of the investment, which will be allocated to asset i = 1,…,N, for buying or selling.

Particularly, additional nonnegative constraints are aided, wi   0, i = 1,…,N, which means that asset i will be bought for the portfolio. The case with negative weights, wi  <  0 means that the investor will sell asset i at time t0 and at the end of the investment period T the will buy these assets to recover his wealth. During these operations the investor has to achieve positive portfolio return. The case of portfolio optimization with negative weights is named “short sells” but it is allowed only for special types of investors [2]. That’s the reason that MPT mainly applies an additional constraint for nonnegative weights w   0 to problems (4) and (5).

To be able to solve problems (4) and (5) the parameters E and have to be numerically evaluated. These parameters are strongly influenced by time. The estimation of the mean assets’ returns Ei, i = 1,…,N, has to be made for historical period. The portfolio manager must use a time series of assets’ returns

R 1 = R 1 1 R 1 2 R 1 n R N = R N 1 R N 2 R N n , E6

where R i m is the return of asset i at time m, i = 1,…,N, m = 1,…,n; n-discrete points from the return history. These return values could be on daily, monthly, weekly basis for a past period of time. Because for that case the time is defined as integer number of days/months/weeks, the number n describes the length of the historical period, taken by the portfolio manager to estimate the mean assets’ returns Ei, 1,…,N. The value of n is a discrete time and it influences the values of the assets’ characteristics. For a discrete time diapason 1  ÷  n the mean assets’ returns are

E i = 1 n 1 m = 1 n R i m , i = 1 , , N . E7

Having the values Ei, i = 1,…,N from (7) the covariance matrix is calculated as

COV . = = c 11 c 1 N c N 1 c N N , c ij = 1 n 1 m = 1 n R i m E i R j m E j , i , j = 1 , , N . E8

The covariance coefficient cij has meaning, which defines how the time series of the assets’ returns i and j behave. The case of positive correlation cij  >  0 means that if the time series of returns Ri of asset increase (or decrease) the same simultaneous change of increase (or decrease) takes place for the time series of returns Rj. For the case of negative correlation cij  <  0, the time series Ri and Rj move in opposite directions. If the time series Ri increase (or decrease) the time series Rj decrease (or increase). The negative correlation has advantage in usage by the portfolio managers to decrease the total risk of the portfolio. Because cij = cji from (8), the covariance matrix ∑ is symmetrical. For the case i = j the value cii is the variation of the row Ri, c ii = σ i 2 , σ i —standard deviation of row Ri. Thus, the covariance matrix on its diagonal gives the variation of the assets’ returns. The components cij define the behavior of the time series of returns Ri and Rm. The portfolio theory applies the variation σ i 2 as quantitative values of the risk of asset i. The graphical interpretation of mean return and risk of asset i is given in Figure 2, where.

Figure 2.

Graphical interpretation of the risk and mean return of asset.

Ri is the dynamically changed return of asset i,

Eithe mean value of return for the time period [t1, t2],

σ i —standard deviation of Ri towards Ei and give value of the risk of asset i.

The risk of the asset graphically represents the diapason [ + σ i , σ i ] between which the real asset returns Ri generally stay around the mean value Ei. After definition of the vector of mean assets’ returns ET = (E1, …, EN) and the covariance matrix COV(.) = , the portfolio return Ep analytically is evaluated as

E p = i = 1 N w i E i = E T w or R p = i = 1 N w i R i = R T w . E9

The value of the portfolio risk is calculated by the quadratic term

σ i 2 = i = 1 N j = 1 n c ij w i w j or σ p 2 = w T w . E10

The MPT uses and integration of the portfolio problems (4) and (5) by definition of a common optimization problem

min w 1 2 1 Ψ w T w Ψ E T w E11
i = 1 N w i = 1 , w i 0 , i = 1 , N .

The value of Ψ is the “risk aversion” coefficient, which is normalized for the numerical diapason [0, 1].

  • For the case Ψ = 0 the investor doesn’t care about the portfolio return and his goal is to achieve minimal portfolio risk.

  • For the case Ψ = 1 the investor targets maximization of the portfolio return without considering the portfolio risk, because min Ψ E T w max + Ψ E T w .

By changing Ψ 0 1 different solutions w opt Ψ are found from problem (11) which gives corresponding returns E p = E T w opt Ψ and risk σ p 2 = w o pt T Ψ w opt Ψ for the portfolios. These set of solutions can be presented as a set of points [ σ p 2 , E p ] in this space which in continuous case origins the “efficient frontier” curve, Figure 3.

Figure 3.

The curve of “efficient frontier” and the market point.

The efficient frontier has quadratic character but it is not a smooth line [3]. This non-smooth character origins from the existence of non-negative constraints wi 0 , i = 1,…,N in problem (11). Hence, the MPT recommends to be defined and solved portfolio problem (11). Because the investors have different ability to undertake risk, the portfolio manager has to estimate the correct value of the “risk aversion” parameter. Because such identification is strongly subjective influenced, the MPT recommends to be evaluated the “efficient frontier” of portfolios. The investor can choose appropriate point from the frontier, which corresponds to the relation Risk/Return, which the investor is willing to accept. The portfolio, applied in problem (11) is named also “mean-variance” (MV) portfolio model. From the time management considerations, the cases which are influenced by the time, for the portfolio problems are summarized as:

  • the portfolio manager has to choose the time for the portfolio implementation;

  • he has to decide the duration of the investment ∆t = T– t 0 ; T—final investment time;

  • he has to choose the duration n of the historical period, which will be used for the evaluation of the mean assets’ returns Ei, i = 1, N and the covariance matrix COV(.) =  of the assets’ returns. The diagonal values of matrix gives assets’ risks σ i 2 , i = 1 , , N .

Thus, the time is very important parameter, which influences the definition and implementation of the portfolio investment and optimization.

Advertisement

4. Capital Market Theory

The MPT originated by the works of Markowitz has its further developments. The next important stage of MPT is the definition of the Capital Market Theory, [2]. The Capital Market Theory introduces a new point on the “efficient frontier,” named “market portfolio.” It has analogical portfolio characteristics as market return E M and market risk σ M 2 . This theory derives new analytical relations with the market characteristics, which are formal part of the Capital Asset Price Model (CAPM). This model added three additional linear relations named Capital Market Line (CML), Security Market Line (SML) and cHaracteristic Line (HL).

The graphical representation of the CML is given in Figure 3. It starts from the point (0, r f ) which is a riskless asset with mean return r f . The market point ( E M , σ M 2 ) is a tangent one over the “efficient frontier.” The CML gives relations between the portfolios returns and risks for a particular market, assessed by the characteristics r f , E M , σ M 2 . Analytically, the CML is a linear relation between E p and σ p ,

E p = r f + E M r f σ M σ p . E12

By estimating the market parameters r f , E M , σ M 2 the investor has information about the level of risk σ p 2 , which has to be undertaken by means to obtain portfolio return E p . This prevents the investor to have unrealistic expectation about the potential mean return, which has to be achieved by a portfolio. The values of the market parameters, E M , σ M 2 are defined mainly according to the behavior of market index (S&P500, Dow Jones Industrial Average, NASDAQ Composite, NYSE Composite, FTSF100, Nikkei225, IPC Mexico, EURONEXT 100 and others). On each market the risk-free assets (deposits, long time bonds) has its own value r f .

The SML introduces linear relations between the mean return of a particular asset E i and the market return E M

E i = r f + E M r f β i . E13

The coefficient “beta” ( β i ) is a value of the relation

β i = cov i M σ M 2 , β i 1 1 E14

The “beta” coefficient takes normalized values from the diapason [−1, 1]. Numerically, it defines how strong the mean return value E i is related with the market return E M . If the return E i is strongly related to the market behavior, the coefficient β i has high value, close to 1, if the covariation coefficient cov(i,M) is positive. The case of β i < 0 means that the covariance between the series of returns Ri and RM are in opposite directions.

The HL line makes additional clarification between the current value of the asset return Ri and market one RM

R i = r f + β i R M r f . E15

Relation (15) is timely influenced. If the market value RM is changed/predicted, the corresponding asset return Ri of asset i can be estimated and/or predicted.

The CAPM does not apply explicit inclusion of time in its characteristics. Time explicitly influences only the values of the market return E M and market risk σ M . Applying the same considerations which take place for the evaluation of the assets’ characteristics Ei, σ i i = 1,…,N the historical period for the evaluation of the market characteristics is recommended to be the same, with n discrete historical values of the market return R M = R M 1 R M 2 R M n .

Advertisement

5. Black-Litterman model for estimation of portfolio characteristics

The Black-Litterman (BL) model is based on both achievements of the MV portfolio model and CAPM. The idea behind the BL model is the ability to use additional information by means to estimate and to predict the assets’ characteristics Ei(T) and σ i T , i = 1,…,N [4, 5, 6]. The difference and the added value N for the future time moment T when the portfolio investment will be capitalized e of the BL model is graphically interpreted in Figure 4.

Figure 4.

Additional modification of portfolio parameters by BL model.

The MV model estimates the assets characteristics Ei, σ i , i = 1,…,N using historical data from n discrete points of the assets’ returns R i m , i = 1 , , N , m = 1 , , n . The BL model allows additional information to be used by means to modify the mean values of return ET = (E1, …, EN) as the assets’ risk characteristics, given by the covariation matrix . The modification of ET to a new vector E BL T = E BL 1 E BLN is made by two additional numerical matrices P and Q. These matrices are evaluated from expert views, who make a subjective assessment about the future levels of assets’ returns at time T, when the portfolio investment should be capitalized.

P is a k×N matrix, which contains k expert views. The vector Q defines quantitative information about the k-th expert view for increase or decrease the mean return Ei of i-th asset. The elements pki of P defines the view of k-th expert about the change of the Ei return of asset i. The component pki takes value +1 for the case of increase, and respectively −1 for decrease.

The BL model added a new contribution to the MPT by introducing new characteristic of the portfolio asset: “implied return,” П i , i = 1 , , N (“implied excess return,” when the return is evaluated according to the level of risk-free asset r f ). These returns differ from the historically evaluated mean returns Ei, i= 1 , , N . The assumption behind these new “implied returns” is related with the existence of market point ( E M , σ M ). For the case of market equilibrium, the CAPM asserts that all assets, which participate on this market should have appropriate mean returns П Т = ( П1, … ПN) and market weights w M T = ( w M 1 ,…, w MN ). Hence from the market values ( E M , σ M ) it follows exact values of П and w. But the market is a stochastic system and it endues a lot of noises, which change the values of the “implied returns.” These returns П i , i = 1 , , N are values, which “should be.” But the noises make changes to П i and the BL model evaluates the unknown mean values EBL which are the “best approximation to П i .” These considerations origin the matrix linear relation in BL model

П = E BL + ε , E BL = E BL 1 E BLN , E16

where the noise ε is assumed to be with normal distribution, zero mean and volatility proportionally decreased from the historical covariance matrix, ε N 0 τ Σ , 0 < τ < 1 . The subjective views formally are introduced by the linear stochastic relation

Q = P E BL + η , E17

where Q is the quantitative assessment of the experts’ views about the value with which the historical returns will change; P identifies which assets’ returns will be changed. The expert views contain also noise η . Due to the independence of the expert views the noise η is assumed with zero mean and volatility Ω , η N 0 Ω . The matrix Ω is kxk square one with only diagonal elements because of the independence of the expert’s views. The matrix Ω is presented mainly in the form [7].

Ω = τ diag P P T E18

The goal of the BL model is the evaluation of the returns E BL which have to approximate in maximal level the stochastic relations (16) and (17). The values of the vectors and matrices П, Q, P, ε , η are assumed to be known and/or estimated. The definitions of these parameters are given in the next paragraph.

Advertisement

6. Definition of the “implied excess returns”

Using [8, 9] the assumption is made that the “implied excess return” П must satisfy the market portfolio. The goal function of the portfolio problem for that case is

min w 1 2 λ w M T w M w M T П , E19

where λ = 1 Ψ Ψ is not normalized value of the risk aversion coefficient, λ 0 . Because the market point is used in (18) according to the CAPM the relation w M T . 1 = 1 is satisfied, 1 T = 1 1 is a unity Nx1 vector. The unconstrained minimization of (19) gives solution

λ w M П = 0 . E20

By multiplication from left of the both sides of (20) with market capitalization weights w M T it follows

λ w M T w M = w M T П . E21

The right component of (21) contains the market “excess return” E M r f , according to (9). The left side gives the market volatility (risk) σ M 2 , (10) or

λ = E M r f σ M 2 . E22

Substituting (22) in (21) the “implied excess return” results as

П = E M r f σ M 2 Σ w M . E23

The “implied return” П* is the value of П to which the riskless return is added

П = П + r f . E24

This manner of definition of П is known as “inverse optimization” because the market risk and return are known, but we need to calculate the asset returns.

Advertisement

7. Definition of P and Q from scientific views

Following [10] absolute and relative manner for the formalization of the expert views are applied. The explanation of these forms of formalization is given with a simple example. Let’s the portfolio contains N = 4 assets. Assuming that an expert expects that the first asset will increase its return with 2%; a second expert makes conclusion that the fourth asset will decrease its return with 3% the formalization of P, Q are

P = 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 1 , Q = 2 3 . E25

The relative form of views applies comparisons between the assets’ returns. Let’s the first expert expects that the first asset will outperform the third one with 2.5%; the second expert makes view that the second asset will outperform the fourth one with 3.5%. The formalization of matrices P and Q are

P = 1 0 1 0 0 1 0 1 , Q = 2.5 3.5 . E26

The two types of formalization of expert views is widely mention in references dealing with the BL model [7, 10]. A new form of expert views has been developed in [11]. It has been applied a weighted form for the definition of matrix P, where its components can take values different from ± 1 . To provide this new formalization of the expert views the matrix Ω is analyzed. This matrix formalizes the variation of the expert views. Using relation (18) let’s assume that the portfolio contains three assets, N = 3 and two experts k = 2 make views in relative form formalized in the matrices P and Q

P = 1 0 1 0 0 1 0 1 , Q = 2 4 . E27

Hence it follows

Ω = τ diag P P T = τ diag 1 0 1 0 0 1 0 1 2 4 , E28

where is a symmetrical 4 × 4 matrix σ 1 2 σ 12 σ 21 σ 31 σ 41 σ 2 2 σ 32 σ 42 σ 13 σ 14 σ 23 σ 3 2 σ 43 σ 24 σ 34 σ 4 2 . The matrix multiplications results in 2 × 2 matrix Ω = ω 1 0 0 ω 2 where

ω 1 = τ σ 1 2 + σ 3 2 2 σ 13 , ω 2 = τ σ 2 2 + σ 4 2 2 σ 24 . E29

Relations (29) have analytical structure with the risk relation of portfolio with two assets, N = 2, and negative correlation, [2] σ p 2 = w 1 2 σ 1 2 + w 2 2 σ 2 2 2 w 1 w 2 σ 12 where σ 1 2 and σ 2 2 are the volatilities of the two assets, σ p 2 is the volatility of the portfolio, σ 12 is the covariation between the two returns. Assuming equal weights in the portfolio, w 1 = w 2 , the portfolio risk is evaluated as

σ p 2 = 0.25 σ 1 2 + σ 2 2 2 σ 12 . E30

The comparisons between relations (29) and (30) can be interpreted that in (29) ω 1 and ω 2 are the values of risks of two virtual portfolios. The first one contains assets one and three. The second portfolio has the second and fourth assets. Thus, the values ω i i = 1 , 2 , which formalize the risk of expert views are proportional to virtual portfolios with corresponding two assets, which have negative correlations and equal weights.

Now let’s assume that the matrix P contains weighted components α i , which differ from the values ± 1 . To simplify the formal notations we assume that the matrix P is on the form.

P = α 1 0 α 3 0 0 α 2 0 α 4 . The weighted coefficients satisfy the equalities

α 1 + α 3 = 1 and α 2 + α 4 = 1 . E31

For that case the corresponding values of the components ω i i = 1 , 2 are

ω 1 = τ α 1 2 σ 1 2 + α 3 2 σ 3 2 2 α 1 α 3 σ 13 , ω 2 = τ α 2 2 σ 2 2 + α 4 2 σ 4 2 2 α 2 α 4 σ 24 . E32

Relations (32) interpret that for the weighted form P( α ) of the expert views the corresponding components ω i i = 1 , 2 of the variation of the expert views are proportional to the risk of a portfolio with two assets and negative correlation, and the assets weights α are normalized because equalities (31) hold. The ability to define matrix P with components different to ± 1 allows the expert views to be generated not only by subjective assessments, but also with additional considerations, which are based on objective criteria, estimations and assessments.

This research makes several additions to the numerical definition of P and Q matrices.

  1. 1. Formalization P( α ) based on the difference ПiEi, i = 1,…,N, normalized by the i-th volatility.

    Following [11] a row of matrix P concerning the view of an expert is defined in the form p s = 0 α i 0 0 α j 0 , 1xN vector. The values α i and α j must satisfy the normalization equation α i + α j = 1 . The value α i is chosen from the maximal difference

α i > 0 max i П i E i σ i 2 , i = 1 , , N . E33

Relation (33) presents that the mean history’ return of asset i, E i , is lower from its “implied excess return” and the investor has to expect that the return of asset i has to increase. The same considerations, but for decrease of the mean return E j is made from the difference

α j < 0 min j П j E j σ j 2 , j = 1 , , N . E34

Asset j is over performed and the investor has to expect decrease of the historical mean return E j towards the level of the “implied excess return” П j .

The value of the component from matrix Q is

q = min i , j П i E i П j E j . E35

  1. 2. Formalization P( П E ) based on the difference ПiEi, i = 1,…,N without normalization with volatilities.

    For that case relations (33) and (34) are slightly modified with lack of volatility normalization

α i > 0 max i П i E i П i E i + П j E j , i , j = 1 , , N E36
α j < 0 min j П j E j П i E i + П j E j , i , j = 1 , , N

  1. 3. Formalization of P( П ) based only on the value of Пi, i = 1,,N.

α i > 0 max i П i П i + П j , i , j = 1 , , N E37
α j > 0 max j П j П i + П j , i , j = 1 , , N

  1. 4. A particular case can arise when all differences α i = ПiEi, i = 1, N have equal sign (+) or (−). Hence all assets’ returns have to be increased, when α i > 0 or decreased if α i < 0 .

For that case absolute views can be assign. The matrix P will be square NxN identity matrix. 1 0 1 0 1 N×N. The Q, N×1 vector will have components equal to α i = ПiEi, i = 1,…,N.

Thus, for the formalization of p. 2 the matrices P and Q are

Q = П 1 E 1 П N E N N × 1 , P = 1 0 1 0 1 N × N . E38
or Q = П = П 1 П N E39

for the case of p. 3. These four forms of weighted formalization of matrix P( α ) allows to be overcome the need to have subjective expert views. With these formalizations the assets’ characteristics are evaluated not only by historical returns and covariances but by adding data, which in this case concerns differences from the “implied returns.” The |BL model incorporates such additional source of information, Figure 4. The formalism P( α ) allows to be compared portfolio solutions, based on MV model and BL one because subjective influences in BL model now are missing. The BL model integrates different sources of information, concerning future assets’ characteristics, but this information is not subjectively generated and it origins from real and actual behavior of the market.

Advertisement

8. BL modification of the assets’ characteristics

Using relations (22) and (23) the BL returns EBL are found by means to approximate in best way these two linear stochastic relations. For simplicity additional notation are used in the next matrix relations

Y = X E BL + ψ , E40

where

Y = П Q , X = I P , ψ = ε η , ψ ¯ = τ Σ 0 0 Ω . E41

The general least square method with the minimization of the Mahalanobis distance

E BL min arg min E BL ( Y X E BL T ψ 1 ¯ ( Y X E BL E42

gives solution

E BL = τ Σ 1 + P T Ω 1 P 1 τ Σ 1 П + P T Ω 1 Q E43

and volatility Vol E BL = BL = τ Σ 1 + P T Ω 1 P 1 .

Taking into account the riskless return, the final BL assets’ returns and covariance matrix are

E BL final = E BL + r f   and   Σ BL final = Σ + BL E44

Using these modified assets’ characteristics, the portfolio problem (11) is solved and appropriate point from the efficient frontier is chosen. It is recommended the best portfolio to be taken with weights w i opt , i = 1 , , N , which belongs to portfolios with characteristics

Maximal Sharp excess ratio , max w E p r f σ p 2 E45
or maximal information ratio , max w E p σ p E46
Advertisement

9. Numerical simulations and comparisons between MV and BL portfolios solutions

The numerical simulations are performed with real data from the Bulgarian Stock Exchange [12]. The riskless investment for several years gives very low or even negative return. That is, the reason for the investors to start to apply portfolio optimization with risky assets. Currently, the risky investments are performed with a set of about 125 mutual funds in Bulgaria nowadays. The mutual funds are operated by different business and economics entities. The goal of all mutual funds is to manage their portfolios by means to achieve positive return or to decrease the losses in nonfriendly behavior of the financial market. The success or not successful management of the mutual funds can be seen by their historical data about achieved returns and risks in their investments. Thus, our portfolio simulations will start with historical return data of a set of chosen Bulgarian mutual funds. It has been chosen seven mutual funds to participate in the portfolio: Concord Asset Management (CONCORD), Elana Asset Management (ELANA), Profit Asset Management (PROFIT), Texim (TEXIM), Central Cooperative Bank Lider (LIDER), Asset Management UBB Patrimonium (PATRIM), Asset Management DSK Growth (GROWTH). They invest both in currencies and shares. The Bulgarian Association of Asset Management Companies [13] and the Government Financial Supervision Commission [14] regularly record and update the activities of the Bulgarian mutual funds. For the simulation experiments it has been taken the mean monthly return of these 7 mutual funds for 2018-year, Figure 5.

Figure 5.

Monthly and annual returns, and the covariance matrix of the mutual funds for 2018.

The calculations in this research have been performed in MATLAB environment. The mean years returns and the covariance matrix are given also in Figure 5. The simulations apply multiperiod investment policy, described in Figure 6.

Figure 6.

Multi period investment with flowing historical window.

9.1 Initial evaluation of historical data

The monthly mean returns of the mutual funds for the first 8 months of 2018 were taken as historical period. It has been calculated the average return for each fund for this historical period, n = 8. The average returns and the corresponding covariance matrix are given in Figure 7.

Figure 7.

Mean returns and covariance matrix for the first 8 months of 2018.

The portfolio manager has to pay attention for the different values of mean returns and covariance, given in Figures 5 and 7. The first case is evaluated for n = 12, 12 time period. While the second evaluations are made for a shorter period, n = 8. That is, a case where the time management is important for the estimation of the assets’ characteristics.

9.2 Evaluation of the efficient frontier with MV model for the first 8 months

By changing the values of Ψ 0 1 the portfolio problem (11) is repeatedly solved. The interim values of the portfolio return, risk and portfolio weights are stored in working arrays in MATLAB environment. The evaluation step of changing Ψ was chosen Ψ = 0.01 resulting in 100 solutions of problem (11). The graphical presentation of the MV “efficient frontier” is given in Figure 8.

Figure 8.

Graphical presentation of the “efficient frontier” with historical data.

The Sharpe excess ratio (45) and the information ratio (46) are presented in Figure 9.

Figure 9.

Graphical presentation of Sharpe excess ratio and information ratio.

It is estimated the maximum Sharpe_excess_ratio = 4.321. This value corresponds to a portfolio with characteristics:

Return = 0.0218 , Risk = 0.0143 , w optT = 0 ;   0.0304 ;   0.9696 ;   0 ;   0 ;   0 ;   0 . E47

These results recommend that the portfolio manager has to allocate his investment only in two mutual funds: the second in the portfolio (ELANA) and the third one (PROFIT). This recommendation is valid for the investment month of September 2018.

9.3 Evaluation of the assets’ characteristics for the BL model

9.3.1 Definition of the risk-free return rf

In this research for the risk-free return rf has been used an official index, evaluated and maintained by the National Bank of Bulgaria. The index is named LEONIA+ which is abbreviation of Lev (the name of the National currency) Over Night Index Average. This index is used by the mutual funds to take or giving loans for overnight activities on the financial market. This index is recommendation from the Bulgarian National Bank for all financial institution and authorities in Bulgaria dealing in overnight deposits with Bulgarian currency [15]. For this research the risk-free value is negative on monthly basis, rf = −0.4.

9.3.2 Evaluation of the market point

The characteristics of the market point are the mean return EM and the risk, numerically estimated by the standard deviation σ M . The market point is found as a tangent one where the CML (Capital Market Line) makes over the “efficient frontier.” Additionally, the CML must pass through the riskless point (0, rf). The CML cannot be presented in analytical way because the “efficient frontier” is not analytically given. The last have been found numerically as a set of points in the plane (Risk/Return) from the multiple solutions of portfolio problem (11), given in p. 2. This research makes a quadratic approximation of the “efficient frontier” and finds analytical description of the “approximated efficient frontier.” Then with algebraic calculations using the linear equation of the CML and the approximated efficient frontier the tangent point is evaluated. The coordinates of the market point give the mean market return EM and the market risk σ M . For these market values the market capitalization weights wM are found from the working arrays when problem (11) has been solved in p. 2. The “approximated efficient frontier” is a quadratic curve of the form

y = a 2 x + a 1 x + a 0 E48

where a2 = −3980.6; a1 = 118.40; a0 = −0.9, x = Risk, y = Return.

The numerical values of the market point are:

EM = 0.0222, σ M 2 = 0.0143, λ = 4.3462 (according to (22)).

The graphical presentation of the CML, the “efficient frontier” and its approximation and the market point are given in Figure 10.

Figure 10.

CML and approximated efficient frontier.

9.3.3 Evaluation of the implied excess returns Пi, i = 1,…,N.

Using relation (23) the “implied excess returns” Пi, i = 1,…,N are:

ПT = [0.0523; −0.0126; 0.0235; 0.0635; 0.0375; 0.0433; 0.0427].

Respectively, the “implied returns” is П* = П +  r f or.

П*T = [0.0923; 0.0274; 0.0635; 0.1035; 0.0775; 0.0833; 0.0827].

9.3.4 Definition of the characteristics of the expert views P and Q

The portfolio parameter, which is used for the estimation of matrices P and Q is the difference between the implied returns П and the mean assets’ historical returns E, (П–Е). These values are as follows:

  1. П*T = [0.0923; 0.0274; 0.0635; 0.1035; 0.0775; 0.0833; 0.0827];

  2. ET = [−0.0592; −0.0424; 0.0238; −0.0105; −0.1277; −0.1141; −0.1216];

  3. *-E)T = [0.1115; 0.0298; −0.0003; 0.0741; 0.1652; 0.1575; 0.1643].

Because the value of the third component of *-E)T is less than 0.1% it is assumed to be zero. All differences *-E) have positive sign, which means that the assets are underestimated and their implied returns are higher. Hence, the portfolio manager has to expect an increase of the mean returns of the assets in the portfolio. This case of differences between implied and mean returns defines the usage of relation (39) for the definition of matrices P and Q. The option (39) is also applied in this simulation work. The calculations have been performed with 7 × 7 identity matrix P, 1 0 1 0 1 7 × 7 and two types of matrices Q:

Q = П E and Q = П . E49

9.3.5 Evaluation of the BL returns EBL and the BL covariance matrix ΣBL

The evaluations of the modified mean assets’ returns EBL according to the BL model are done according to relations (43) and (44). The value of the covariance matrix of the expert views is assumed to be as the historical covariance but the values of its components are decreased with equal value τ . Thus the covariance matrix of the expert views is τ where the value of τ must be between 0 and 1. From practical recommendations [7, 16, 17], this research uses τ = 0.5 . The BL model evaluations are.

E BL T = 0.0523 0.0126 0.0235 0.0635 0.0375 0.0433 0.0427 ; E50
Σ BL = 0.1588 0.0873 0.0219 0.0416 0.0252 0.0490 0.1675 0.0873 0.0816 0.0040 0.0199 0.0198 0.0593 0.1130 0.0219 0.0040 0.0172 0.0272 0.0198 0.0193 0.0163 0.0416 0.0199 0.0272 0.0566 0.0310 0.0044 0.0398 0.0252 0.0198 0.0198 0.0310 0.0456 0.0921 0.0681 0.0490 0.0593 0.0193 0.0044 0.0921 0.3113 0.1696 0.1675 0.1130 0.0163 0.0398 0.0681 0.1696 0.3424 E51

9.3.6 Solution of portfolio problem with E BL T and ΣBL

The portfolio problem (11) is repetitively solved by changing Ψ 0 1 with the BL evaluations of the assets’ characteristics E BL T and ΣBL. The new BL “efficient frontier” is found as a set of numerically evaluated points (100 points). For illustration purposes both “efficient frontiers” with historical data (MV model) and BL data (BL model) are given in Figure 11.

Figure 11.

Efficient frontiers with MV and BL models.

9.3.7 Evaluation of the BL weights w BL opt

The portfolio which has maximum Sharpe excess ratio is identified. This maximum is found from the numerically evaluated points of the BL “efficient frontier.” The needed portfolio parameters are stored in the arrays in MATLAB, during the sequential solutions of problem (11). The Sharpe excess ratio evaluated from (45) gives:

Return BL = 0.0201 , Risk BL = 0.0155 , w BL optT = 0 0.0924 0.9076 0 0 0 0 . E52

The difference between w BL opt and wopt shows a bit increase of the weight for the second asset (PROFIT) for the BL portfolio.

9.4 Comparison of the MV solution wopt and the BL one w BL opt

The optimal weights w BL opt and wopt are assumed to be implemented as portfolio solutions in the beginning of month of September 2018. At the end of this month we can estimate the actual mean returns of the assets for month of September Ef and the modified actual covariation matrix f which is calculated again for 8 months history but from February to September 2018.

  • For the case when the MV weights wopt are invested the investor results will be

Return MV f = E f T w opt , Risk MV f = w optT f w op t . E53

  • For the case when w BL opt weights are applied the investor results will be

Return BL f = E f T w BL opt , Risk BL f = w BL optT f w BL opt . E54

Then these portfolio results will be compared in the space Risk(Return). The portfolio point which is situated far on the Nord-West direction of the Risk(Return) space is the preferable portfolio. Such assessment will prove which portfolio model MV or BL gives more benefit and efficiency.

9.5 Multiperiod portfolio optimization

Following Figure 6 a next portfolio investment with MV and BL models is done by moving the history period 1 month ahead. The portfolio evaluations are done for a history period from February till September 2018. The evaluated weights w BL opt and wopt are applied for the month of October. For this case of 8 months historical period and available data for all 12 months of 2018 such multiperiod investment policy will evaluate 4 portfolios using the two models MV and BL. This research did three modifications of the BL model, concerning the evaluation of the matrices P and Q, related to the views for changing the assets characteristics:

For the cases when all components ( П E ) or П have same sign, the procedures (32) or (33) are applied. The obtained results are given in Table 1.

MV model BL model
P( α ) P( П E ) P( П )
Return (MV)f Risk (MV)f Return (BL)f Risk (BL)f Return (BL)f Risk (BL)f Return (BL)f Risk (BL)f
0.1080 0.0133 0.1017 0.0132 0.1055 0.0132 0.1122 0.0129
−0.0187 0.0117 −0.0931 0.0120 −0.0632 0.0111 −0.0221 0.0106
−0.4011 0.0282 −0.3861 0.0263 −0.3793 0.0255 −0.4088 0.0292
−0.3525 0.0240 −0.2313 0.0114 −0.1523 0.0080 −0.2028 0.0106
Mean values
−0.1661 0.0193 −0.1552 0.0157 −0.1223 0.0145 −0.1304 0.0158

Table 1.

Results of multi-period portfolio management with MV and BL models.

The graphical presentation of the comparison of the multiperiod portfolio management between MV and BL with P( П ) modification is given in Figure 12.

Figure 12.

Comparison of multiperiod MV and BL(P(П)) portfolio optimization.

The common results prove that the market situation in 2018 does not allow the mutual funds to achieve positive return. The results are negative but this negative value is less than the riskless return value rf = −0.4. Hence, the portfolio management allows reduction of the losses. Particularly, all three modifications of the BL model give better results in comparison with the classical MV portfolio model. The mean values of the returns with BL model are very close to the returns of the MV model. But the risk values are considerably lower, which means that the probability to be closer to the mean values of BL returns is higher than the case of MV model.

Advertisement

10. Time management considerations for the portfolio investments

This research illustrates that the task of portfolio investment is quite complicated. The meaning of portfolio optimization concerns the definition and solution of portfolio problem. In both these tasks the time is a prerequisite for successful portfolio investment.

10.1 Time requirements for the stage of definition of the portfolio problem

The content in the paragraph “Portfolio optimization problem” explicitly asserts that the investor has to choose the duration of the historical period. This duration, n is in discrete form. It has to be chosen in a way that can refer to the investment period (T-t0). Obviously, high number of n will give influence for the slow changes in the market behavior. Respectively, the active portfolio management will not benefit with long duration of the historical period n.

The active management needs to follow the current dynamics of the market. The relations between n and (T-t0) cannot be derived on theoretical basis. Only practical considerations could be useful. The authors’ experience recommends duration of the historical period to be considered between 6 and 8 months. Such history period can be used for multiperiod portfolio management from 1 to 3 months ahead in the future.

An unexpected problem has been met by the authors, concerning the relation between the historical discrete points n and the number N of the assets, included in the portfolio. The two parameters n and N participate both for the evaluation of the covariance matrix ∑. This matrix should be in full rank by means that the portfolio problem (11) must generate regular solutions. If the rank of ∑ is less than N problem (11) gives unrealistic solutions. To keep ∑ with rank N it is needed its components to be evaluated with historical data n > N. The practical minimal case is n + 1 = N but before solving the portfolio problem the investor has to check the rank of ∑. As practical consideration, if the portfolio contains many assets and N is high, the data from the historical period n have to be also high. For that case one can use not only monthly returns but also weekly average data. Thus, the value of n can increase.

10.2 Time requirements for the solution of the portfolio problem

The solution of the portfolio problem (11) gives unique set of weights, which have to be implemented for the portfolio investment. Because the market behavior changes, reasonable policy is to perform repeatedly definition and solution of the portfolio problem. Potential beneficial strategy can be the multiperiod portfolio management, presented in Figure 6. It incorporates the multiperiod management and adopts the portfolio parameters with up to date market data. The relation between the duration of the historical period and the investment period is still an open question. But making additional simulations with 1, 2, 3 or more months (time) ahead the portfolio manager can change his decision on each investment step.

11. Conclusions

This research identifies in explicit way the influence of the time for the definition and solution of portfolio problems. These time requirements are considerably related with the estimation of the parameters of the portfolio problem. Respectively, the time requirements insist the portfolio management to be performed in multiperiod investment.

This research makes an analysis of the development of the portfolio theory. Starting with the Markowitz formalization, the MV portfolio problems are based only on historical data about mean returns and covariances between the returns. The development of CAPM gives new relations, originated from a new “market” point. The last gives additional information about the values of the parameters of the portfolio problem. Finally, the BL model introduces a new set of points, “implied excess returns,” which originate from the market point. As a result, new values for the parameters of the portfolio problem are found. Respectively, the portfolio problem gives weights of the assets, which are not sharp cut, which decreases the risk of the investment.

This research introduces new modifications of the BL model for the part of definition of expert views. Particularly the experts are substituted by additional data, which origins from the dynamical behavior of the assets’ returns. Thus, not only mean returns and covariances are taken into consideration, but also the difference between objective parameters as implied and historical mean returns. These modifications allow the portfolio model MV and these based on BL one to be compared on a common basis and to assess their performances. Such comparison cannot be made if subjective experts are used, because their mutual views will be different for the same historical data and with changes the members of the experts.

This research gives also a practical added value with the analysis of the behavior of the market with mutual funds in Bulgaria. This gives additional experience and bases for future comparisons and assessments of the different portfolio models.

Acknowledgments

This work has been partly supported by project H12/8, 14.07.2017 of the Bulgarian National Science fund: Integrated bi-level optimization in information service for portfolio optimization, contract ДH12/10, 20.12.2017.

References

  1. 1. Markowitz H. Portfolio selection. Journal of Finance. 1952;7:77-91
  2. 2. Sharpe W. Portfolio Theory and Capital Markets. New York: McGraw Hill; 1999, 316 p. Available from: https://www.amazon.com/Portfolio-Theory-Capital-Markets-William/dp/0071353208
  3. 3. Merton C. An analytic derivation of the efficient portfolio frontier. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis. 1972;7(4):1851-1872. DOI: 10.2307/2329621. Available from: https://www.jstor.org/stable/2329621?seq=1#page_scan_tab_contents. http://www.stat.ucla.edu/∼nchristo/statistics_c183_c283/analytic_derivation_frontier.pdf
  4. 4. Kolm N, Ritter G. On the Bayesian interpretation of Black-Litterman. European Journal of Operational Research. 2017;258(2):564-572. Available from: https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2853158
  5. 5. Palczewski A, Palczewski J. Black-Litterman model for continuous distributions. European Journal of Operational Research. 2018;273(2):708-720. DOI: 10.1016/j.ejor.2018.08.013, Available from: https://ideas.repec.org/a/eee/ejores/v273y2019i2p708-720.html
  6. 6. Pang T, Karan C. A closed-form solution of the black-Litterman model with conditional value at risk. Operations Research Letters. 2018;46(1):103-108. DOI: 10.1016/j.orl.2017.11.014. Available from: https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0167637717306582?via%3Dihub
  7. 7. He G, Litterman R. The Intuition behind Black-Litterman Model Portfolios. New York: Investment Management Research, Goldman Sachs & Company; 1999. Available from: https://faculty.fuqua.duke.edu/∼charvey/Teaching/IntesaBci_2001/GS_The_intuition_behind.pdf. https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=334304
  8. 8. Walters J. The Black-Litterman Model in Detail. 2014. Available from: https://systematicinvestor.wordpress.com/2011/11/16/black-litterman-model/
  9. 9. Walters J. Reconstructing the Black-Litterman Model. 2014. Available from: https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2330678
  10. 10. Satchell S, Scowcroft A. A demystification of the black–Litterman model: Managing quantitative and traditional portfolio construction. Journal of Asset Management. 2000;1(2):138-150. DOI: 10.1057/palgrave.jam.2240011. Available from: https://link.springer.com/chapter/10.1007%2F978-3-319-30794-7_3. https://www.researchgate.net/publication/31962785_A_demystification_of_the_Black-Litterman_model_Managing_quantitative_and_traditional_portfolio_construction
  11. 11. Vladimirov M, Stoilov T, Stoilova K. New formal description of expert views of Black-Litterman asset allocation model. Journal Cybernetics and Information Technologies. 2017;17(4):87-98. DOI: 10.1515/cait-2017-0043, Available from: http://www.cit.iit.bas.bg/CIT_2017/v-17-4/05_paper.pdf
  12. 12. URL1. Available from: http://infostock.bg
  13. 13. URL2. Available from: www.baud.bg
  14. 14. URL3. Available from: www.fsc.bg
  15. 15. URL4. Available from: https://www.bnb.bg/Statistics/StBIRAndIndices/StBILeoniaPlus/index.htm
  16. 16. Allaj E. The Black-Litterman model: A consistent estimation of the parameter tau. Financial Markets and Portfolio Management. 2013;27(2): 217-251 DOI: 10.1007/s11408-013-0205-x. Available from: https://www.researchgate.net/publication/257417995_The_Black-Litterman_model_A_consistent_estimation_of_the_parameter_tau
  17. 17. Allaj E. The Black-Litterman model and views from a reverse optimization procedure: An out-of-sample performance evaluation. Electronic Journal. July 18 2017:1-32. DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2999335. Available from: papers.ssrn.com/sol3/Papers.cfm?abstract_id=2999335

Written By

Todor Atanasov Stoilov, Krasimira Petrova Stoilova and Miroslav Dimitrov Vladimirov

Submitted: 07 June 2019 Reviewed: 02 August 2019 Published: 14 September 2019