Open access peer-reviewed chapter

Voluntary Private Health Insurance Demand by Older People in a National Health Service, the Case of Portugal

Written By

Aida Isabel Tavares

Submitted: 06 February 2022 Reviewed: 29 April 2022 Published: 31 May 2022

DOI: 10.5772/intechopen.105100

From the Edited Volume

Health Insurance

Edited by Aida Isabel Tavares

Chapter metrics overview

105 Chapter Downloads

View Full Metrics

Abstract

The Portuguese health system is mainly described as a National Health Service (NHS). In parallel with the NHS, there are some Bismarkean features, like those arising from the existence of occupation-based health insurance. On top of these two layers of health insurance coverage, there is a market for private health insurance on a voluntary basis, which older people may not be able to access. The purpose of this work is to estimate the main determinants for older people in Portugal to buy private health insurance since no previous studies have been published. We use data collected by the National Health Survey of 2014 and estimate a multivariate probit. The main results are aligned with previous studies relating to income, education, and age. The role of the health status and behavior explaining the demand for private health insurance, in our results are mixed. People benefiting from parallel occupation-based insurance schemes are less likely to have a private voluntary health insurance policy. The results obtained in this work confirm that there is some inequality in health care access, to the detriment of older people.

Keywords

  • voluntary health insurance
  • determinants
  • older people
  • NHS
  • Portugal

1. Introduction

The Portuguese health system is mainly described as a National Health Service (NHS), following the Beveridge tradition, with universal coverage and mandatory participation. In parallel with the NHS, there are some Bismarkean features, such as those arising from the existence of occupation-based health insurance, which are also mandatory or quasi-mandatory. On top of these two layers of health insurance coverage, there is a market for private health insurance on a voluntary basis. This insurance is both supplementary and complementary to the NHS. People may be interested in buying a health insurance policy because it gives them faster access to health care, lets them choose the provider and enjoy a better experience when admitted to a hospital, and have access to services not included in the NHS, such as dental care [1].

Over the last 6 years, health care expenditure on private VHI in Portugal as a percentage of GDP has been less than 0.5% and it has been about 5% of current health expenditure [2]. Despite this trend, voluntary private health insurance in Portugal grew by about 3.5% between 2012 and 2015 [3].

The insurance market is characterized by asymmetric information [4, 5] expressed by moral hazard [6] and by adverse selection [7]. A moral hazard happens after the insurance contract has been signed and it refers to the situation where the insured person uses more health care services than they would need. On the other hand, adverse selection happens before the insurance contract has been signed, when the insurance company cannot assess the risk type of individual purchasing the insurance. This individual may be a low health risk, so they will be mainly healthy and generate low health care spending, or they may be high risk and will generate high health care spending. If the adverse selection does not take place, then low-risk individuals might prefer to buy the insurance and this is called advantageous or propitious selection [8], which is beneficial to insurance companies. This situation is often explained by a person’s risk preferences. Healthy people tend to be risk-averse and so they choose to buy VHI [9, 10].

Older people are often considered as high health risk individuals, who are very likely to have more health problems than younger individuals, have higher medical expenditures, and raise the claims paid by insurance companies [11]. Not only do these people have more health problems, but insurance companies face moral hazards and adverse selection issues that result in the overuse of health care and the payment of excessive claims. For these reasons, older people are not usually the customers desired by insurance companies.

The Portuguese health insurance market is not as highly regulated as it is in other countries, because health insurance is voluntary and the NHS has universal coverage. So, insurance companies can adopt several strategies to prevent or mitigate moral hazard and adverse selection [12] and to reduce paying out excessive claims. One strategy could involve the eligibility requirements excluding people older than 65. Even though this cream-skimming strategy discriminates against older people, there is a small health insurance market for older people in Portugal. In the last available National Health Survey, conducted in 2014, of the 5,701 people older than 65 interviewed, 5.8% of them stated they had a voluntary health insurance policy.

The purpose of this work is to estimate the main determinants for older people in Portugal to take out private health insurance since no previous studies have been published and there may be differences across European countries [13, 14]. We use data collected by the 2014 National Health Survey and we estimate a multivariate probit. We also compute the marginal effects associated with the most important variables. This analysis provides insights for designing health and social policies that will reduce the inequality in health care access that may be generated by differences in health insurance coverage.

1.1 Demand determinants for voluntary private health insurance

The factors explaining the demand for VHI are well discussed in the literature. While Outreville [15] focused on the demand for insurance in general, [16, 17] have looked at the demand for VHI and reviewed the determinants for buying it; [1] outlined these determinants for the EU countries. The explanatory factors include the demographic and economic determinants (also referred to as socioeconomic status), that is, gender, age, education, income, marital status, employment status, and other characteristics [11, 13, 16, 17, 18, 19]. In general, we can say that the likelihood of purchasing VPHI increases with age, income, education, being employed, and living in urban areas. The results are not conclusive for determinants, such as gender, family composition, and being a pensioner.

In Europe, where health systems tend to be mandatory and offer universal coverage, the determinants for holding a private VHI differ between countries [13, 14]. Regarding Portugal, an empirical study performed almost 20 years ago [20], concluded that the VHI buyers were most likely young, self-employed, living in urban areas, and receiving a middle to high income, thus leaving out older people.

The focus on the demand for private VHI by older people has been much less studied because it is known that as we age, the likelihood of having this type of insurance decreases [21]. Four empirical works should be mentioned that are concerned exclusively with older people and use the data collected by SHARE – Survey of Health, Aging, and Retirement in Europe [18, 13, 14, 19]. In general, being female, having had a good education, and receiving a higher income increases the demand for private VHI by older people.

Special attention is often given to the role of the health status and health behavior since there are proxies for the individual healthrisk type [22]. Health status can be measured by self-assessed health and the presence (or the number) of chronic diseases [18, 23], while health behavior can be proxied by body mass index or being overweight [24], and by smoking decisions [25].

The theory predicts that high-risk individuals are more likely to have health insurance, that is, adverse selection exists in health insurance. However, there are no conclusive empirical results regarding the relationship between individual risk variables and having a VHI policy [16]. This means that advantageous selection is a possibility, where low-risk type people choose to buy health insurance [23, 26].

The empirical results regarding indicators of health status and health-related behavior are mixed. Some studies have found that people reporting better health are more likely to have voluntary health insurance, supporting the hypothesis of advantageous selection [11, 12, 14, 18, 23, 27, 28, 29]; other authors found no significant correlation [27, 30]; and still, others found that healthy people tend to have VHI less often, as predicted by adverse selection hypothesis [11, 12, 14, 19].

In most studies, indicators of chronic diseases are found to be insignificant when explaining the demand for VHI [29, 31, 32]. Few works have reported a positive correlation between suffering from chronic diseases and having private health insurance [18, 23].

The relationship between health-related behaviors and private VHI coverage has been studied less and the results are mixed [14]. While some studies find that smokers are less likely to have VHI [27, 33], others find the opposite [18]. The results are similarly mixed for overweight people. It may be found that being overweight is associated with lower odds of taking out VHI or more likely [24].

1.2 Overview of the Portuguese health system

The Portuguese Health System, created in 1979, is defined as a National Health Service; it is mainly financed through taxes and is a universal coverage system. This means it covers all residents and most medical services.

In parallel with the NHS, there are occupation-based health insurance schemes. These include the public insurance schemes that cover civil servants (called ADSE), the armed forces (called ADM), and also private insurance that covers bank employees (called SAMS), among others. There are other, smaller, occupation-based health insurance plans. All the social contributions under these professional insurance policies are income based.

The Portuguese health system comprises conventional private health insurance and it is non-compulsory. Voluntary health insurance (VHI) provides faster access to appointments and treatments, which are also provided by the NHS, or provides access to services not covered by the NHS, such as dental care.

According to NHS rules, people should be registered with an NHS general practitioner, for primary care, and access to specialists in the NHS is controlled by general practitioner gatekeeping. However, people covered by insurance have direct access to specialists (provided by the private sector) according to the rules of the insurance, and private physicians can refer patients to NHS hospitals. So, having an insurance policy on top of NHS coverage has some advantages when it comes to accessing health care services [3]. These reasons for health care access and quality might justify the demand for private VHI by older people in Portugal.

Advertisement

2. Research design

2.1 Data and sample

We use data collected by the National Health Survey, which are representative of the Portuguese Population [34]. It is harmonized and regulated at the European level (EU regulation no 141/2013). It includes 18,204 individuals and our sample considers those aged over 65, that is, 5,701 individuals.

2.2 Variables

2.2.1 Dependent variable

The dependent variable is given by the question if the individual has voluntary health insurance. This is a binary variable that takes value 1 if the respondent has private health insurance and 0 otherwise.

2.2.2 Independent variables

Independent variables are grouped into five categories—demographic, socioeconomic, marital status, health status, related behavior, and insurance status. These variables are described in Table 1.

Group of variablesIndependent variablesDescription
DemographicMaleDummy variable. Takes value 1 is male, 0 otherwise
AgeOrdinal variable. Age is grouped into 15 classes. The first class takes value 1 and comprises ages 15–19; the last class takes value 15 and includes people older than 85. The variable is taken as continuous.
Socio-economicEducationOrdinal variable. Education is grouped into five levels of education. First level 0 is those without schooling; fifth and last level is 5 and includes people with a college education. The variable is taken as continuous.
IncomeOrdinal variable. Income is grouped into five classes that represent the quantile of net monthly income per equivalent adult. The first value of income corresponds to the first quantile of income. The variable is taken as continuous.
UrbanDummy variable. Takes value 1 if the area is densely inhabited, 0 otherwise.
RuralDummy variable. Takes value 1 if the area is sparsely inhabited, 0 otherwise.
Moderate urbanReference category.
Marital statusSingleDummy variable. Takes value 1 if person is single; 0 otherwise.
MarriedDummy variable. Takes value 1 if person is married; 0 otherwise.
DivorcedDummy variable. Takes value 1 if person is divorced; 0 otherwise.
WidowReference category.
Health status and related behaviorSAHOrdinal variable. Measures self-assessed health and ranges 1–5, where 1 means “very bad” and 5 “very good” health. The variable is taken as continuous.
Chronic diseasesDummy variable. Takes value 1 if person suffers from at least one chronic disease; 0 otherwise.
SmokingDummy variable. Takes value 1 if person smokes; 0 otherwise.
BMIBody Mass Index.
Insurance statusADSEDummy variable. Takes value 1 if person is covered through ADSE insurance; 0 otherwise.
SAMSDummy variable. Takes value 1 if person is covered through SAMS insurance; 0 otherwise.
Other insuranceDummy variable. Takes value 1 if person has another occupational-based health insurance on top of NHS; 0 otherwise.
NHSReference category. This is the case where respondents do not hold any occupational-based health insurance.

Table 1.

Description of independent variables.

2.3 Quantitative analysis

The model to be estimated in this analysis is written as follows:

VHIi*=constant+βiXi+εiand={1ifVHIi*00ifVHIi*<0.E1

where VHI* is the latent dependent variable, VHI is the observable dependent variable, βi’s are the coefficients to be estimated, Xi’s are the independent variables, and εi is the residual.

The dependent variable expresses whether the respondent has voluntary health insurance. The binary nature of this variable implies that the econometric method of estimation is a probit. The estimated coefficients provide the direction of the relation between independent and dependent variables. The computation of the marginal effects allows the comparison of the intensity of the estimated coefficients. The marginal effects provide information on how the probability of having VHI changes when there is a unit change in the independent variable.

The results are obtained using Stata 15 econometric software.

Advertisement

3. Results

3.1 Descriptive statistics

The sample comprises 5,701 respondents older than 65, of whom 85.4% are retired. Only 332 respondents say that they have private voluntary health insurance, the large majority (about 94%) do not. Most of them are not entitled to any other insurance coverage apart from the NHS, and only about 10% are covered by ADSE, the occupation-based insurance plan for public workers (Table 2).

Group of variablesIndependent variablesDescriptive statistics
Number%
DemographicMale
Male2,21538.85
Female3,48661.15
Age
65–691,53326.89
70–741,31923.14
75–791,25922.08
80–8497917.17
+8561110.72
Socio-economic statusEducation (years)
01,94234.06
62,93851.53
93536.19
121893.32
15140.25
172654.65
Income (quantile)
Q11,36824.00
Q21.53426.91
Q31.17420.59
Q486715.21
Q575813.30
Level of urbanization
Urban1,56327.42
Median1,68929.63
Rural2,44942.96
Retired
Yes4,86985.4
Other status83214.6
Marital statusMarital status
Single3636.37
Married2,91351.10
Widow(er)2,13237.40
Divorce2935.14
Health status and related behaviorSAH
1. Very bad5429.51
2. Bad1,44325.33
3. Fair2,81749.45
4. Good78713.81
5. Very good1081.90
Chronic diseases
None77813.65
At least one4,99286.35
Smoker
Yes2664.7
No5,43395.3
BMI
Average27.0
Insurance statusInsurance
None (only NHS)4,83684.83
ADSE5669.93
SAMS831.46
Other insurance2163.78

Table 2.

Descriptive statistics.

The remaining descriptive statistics for the independent variables are also shown in Table 2. The majority of the people in the sample are women (circa 61%) and most of them are aged between 65 and 75. Portuguese older people have very low levels of education, with more than 80% having less than 6 years of schooling. They have very low levels of income, about 50% receive an income valued in the first and second quintile of per capita household income. A large share of the people in the sample live in rural areas (circa 43%), and most of them are married or used to be married.

Finally, regarding their health status, the majority of older Portuguese assess their health status below the median level and about 86% of them report suffering from at least one chronic disease.

Other descriptive statistics regarding the distribution of respondents with private health insurance across income, education, and self-assessed health are shown in Table 3. Considering those individuals who said they had private health insurance (332 people), their distribution across income shows that a larger share of respondents has a high-income level. The distribution of people with health insurance across levels of education has two peaks, one at 6 years of schooling and the other at 17 years of schooling. The distribution of the health status of people having an insurance policy shows that most people with health insurance report a health status better than fair.

Income
QuantileQ1Q2Q3Q4Q5
number21315066164
%6.39.315.119.949.4
Education
years069121517
number301206342374
%9.136.119.012.70.022.3
SAH
levels12345
number10431729017
%3.013.051.827.15.1

Table 3.

Distribution of respondents with voluntary health insurance.

To finish the description of the variables, we now report the correlation between health risk indicators. The pairwise correlation between SAH and suffering from chronic diseases is equal to −0.364 and between SAH and smoking it is equal to 0.107, both for a statistical significance of less than 0.001. The tetrachoric correlation between smoking and suffering from a chronic disease is equal to −0.257 for an identical statistically significant level. So, there is no strong correlation that could prevent the joint utilization of these variables in a regression analysis.

3.2 Model results

The results obtained with the estimation of the probit for having voluntary health insurance are presented in Table 4. The statistically significant coefficients at 5% are marked with *.

Coef.Std. Err.P > z
DemographicMale0,0610,0680,370
Age group
70–74−0.1320.0770.085
75–79−0.226*0.0890.011
80–84−0.497*0.1200.000
+85−0.469*0.1480.002
Socio-EconomicEducation0.073*0.0090.000
Income
Q20.0510.1210.672
Q30.353*0.1160.002
Q40.542*0.1170.000
Q50.988*0.1220.000
Urban0.1120.0770.146
Rural0.0420.0770.588
Retired−0.0730.0870.399
Marital statusSingle−0.367*0.1810.043
Married−0.0390.1180.738
Widow(er)−0.1930.1310.141
InsuranceADSE−0.647*0.1080.000
SAMS−0.2000.1790.265
Other insurance−0.410*0.1490.006
Health status and health behaviorSAH
20.1280.1600.424
30.2120.1500.159
40.330*0.1640.044
50.3920.2260.083
Chronic diseases0.180*0.0910.047
BMI−0.0060.0080.405
Smoking−0.277*0.1350.041
_cons−2.2850.3180.000
Number of obs5,509
LR chi2(26)518.92
Prob > chi20.000
Pseudo R20.207
Log likelihood−994.916

Table 4.

Probit results.

Note: * Significant at less than 5%.

The estimated coefficients show that as someone gets old or is single, the probability of having private health insurance decreases, while for higher income or education levels that probability increases.

Regarding the insurance status of people, being a beneficiary of ADSE or another occupation-based insurance decreases the odds of having private VHI. Lastly, the results for health status and health-related behavior are mixed. On the one hand, higher levels of SAH may be related to having VHI, but on the other hand, suffering from a chronic disease is also positively related to having VHI; additionally, the observable behavior of smoking results in a lower likelihood of benefiting from VHI coverage.

The marginal effects associated with the most important and statistically significant coefficients are presented in Table 5.

dy/dxStd.Err.P > z
Age group
70–74−0.0150.0080.083
75–79−0.0240.0090.009
80–84−0.0440.0090.000
+85−0.0420.0110.000
Income
Q20.0030.0060.670
Q30.0250.0080.002
Q40.0450.0100.000
Q50.1170.0160.000
Education0.0070.0010.000
ADSE−0.0630.0110.000
SAMS−0.0190.0170.265
SAH
20.0100.0120.402
30.0180.0110.112
40.0300.0140.026
50.0380.0240.109
Chronic diseases0.0170.0090.047
Smoking−0.0270.0130.041

Table 5.

Marginal effects.

These effects represent the change in the probability of having a VHI policy after the discrete change from the base level of the independent variable. In this way, the change to the oldest age groups implies a decrease of about 4% in the probability of having VHI, while the change from the lowest income quintile to the highest expresses an increase of 11% in the probability of being covered by VHI. Being a member of ADSE results in a 6% less chance of having VHI, and finally, the change from poor health status to a better one increases the likelihood of benefiting from a VHI; for instance, it increases almost 4% for people reporting very good health.

Advertisement

4. Discussion

In Europe, health systems tend to be mandatory and offer universal coverage. Despite this major trend, there is a market for voluntary private health insurance. Portugal is characterized by having a National Health Service of universal coverage with distinctive features of mandatory occupation-based insurance. Because the health insurance market suffers from asymmetric information, insurance companies adopt cream-skimming strategies to minimize adverse selection and moral hazards. One such strategy is to set the eligibility requirement for buying an insurance health policy is having to be under 65. In this way, most older people are unable to buy a health insurance policy. However, there is a small market and about 5% of Portuguese older people report having voluntary private health insurance of some kind.

Our aim in this work was to find the main determinants of the demand for private health insurance by older people in Portugal and contribute to the literature on voluntary health insurance schemes in different European countries, as there is no study for Portugal. We used data collected by the 2014 National Health Survey and estimated a probit for people over 65 having private health insurance.

The main results are aligned with previous studies concerning the importance of income and education [11, 16, 17, 18, 19]. The higher the income and the better educated the individuals, the greater the probability of having private health insurance.

Concerning age and health insurance, we found that as they get older, they are less likely to have private voluntary health insurance [23, 35, 36]. The results show that only a minority of individuals, about 332 people, have a voluntary private health insurance policy. These people tend to have a high income and a high level of education, which is uncommon among people older than 65. Most older people in Portugal receive small pensions and have a low level of formal education, which deters them from taking out health insurance. The lack of schooling is the origin of illiteracy, both financial and health-related, which precludes people from making wiser choices on how to make better use of their savings and reduce future out-of-pocket expenditures. One major concern relates to dental care and the (high) associated cost. This aspect of health care is usually neglected by older people because it is not covered by the NHS and because they do not have a complementary private health insurance policy to cover it [37, 38].

Regarding the role of health status and behavior in explaining the demand for private health insurance, our results are mixed. On the one hand, there is some evidence of advantageous selection because better health status and no smoking are associated with taking out health insurance. On the other, reported suffering from chronic diseases is also associated with health insurance, this time reflecting adverse selection.

It could be that insurance companies are discriminating based on observable traits, such as smoking. Or, related to high health risks, such as suffering from a chronic disease, it may be the case that people fail to report them. Perhaps insurance companies do not “cream skim” based on these conditions, either because they lack sufficient reliable information, or because they may calculate the probability that a person suffers from a certain disease at a certain age, or even because the insurance company can control claims associated with those health conditions by cost-sharing.

Another explanation of the mixed results found when relating health risk to health insurance is based on the demand side of the market. Maybe there is heterogeneity in the risk preferences of older people. In some countries, healthier individuals might be more risk-averse [14, 16] and so they are more prone to take out voluntary health insurance. Maybe this is the case with Portugal as it was with the UK [39]. On the other hand, people suffering from chronic diseases have a default health status that they consider to be a reference status in the sense proposed by the prospect theory [40]. These people may thus tend to be risk-averse with reference to their health status, and consequently, they are also more prone to have a private health insurance policy.

Finally, regarding the existence of parallel occupation-based insurance plans, our results indicate that people benefiting from ADSE, the largest occupation-based insurance for public servants, or from any other form of private or public health insurance (public health insurance is for the armed forces; private insurance includes bank workers, Portugal – Telecom workers, and postal CTT workers) are less likely to have VHI. This is expected to happen because occupation-based insurances provide a second layer of health coverage on top of the universal provided by the NHS. People benefiting from occupation-based insurance policies pay taxes to finance the NHS and pay a percentage of their income to finance occupation-based insurance. Therefore, this double financing by people deters them from looking for additional private health insurance coverage. In fact, these people do not need private health insurance because their health care needs are covered either by the NHS or by their occupation-based insurance.

The organization of the Portuguese health system creates inequity in access to health care. In the first place, people with double coverage have easier access to health care, and then people with high incomes can afford to buy private health insurance coverage. On top of this, inequality is aggravated by a tax system that gives some benefits to wealthier people for buying private health insurance or for spending on private health care [1]. The findings reported in this work confirm the existence of this sort of inequality, especially among older people.

One limitation of this work is that it is not possible to analyze the type of coverage provided to older people by voluntary private health insurance. This sort of information would show us what health care services older people want, and what could be lacking in the supply of NHS.

The results found in our analysis provide some insights into what makes older people decide to take out voluntary private health insurance. We have concluded that income is a determinant factor for taking out private health insurance, but it is also a factor for generating inequality in health care access. Older people can find it hard to access dental care or simple eye care because it is not covered by the NHS, or because the NHS waiting lists are too long. But the difficulty of complementing NHS coverage with private health insurance increases health care access inequity. Health and social policies may aim to narrow the gap either by providing health care in the NHS or by subsidizing the purchase of private health insurance for low-income older people. The first approach to this has already been put into place. The instrument called “dentist-check” for older people, created by the Ministry of Health attempts to mitigate the inequality in access to dental care, but it needs to be assessed.

Highlights

  • small share of older people buy voluntary private health insurance

  • higher income and higher education increase the likelihood of holding voluntary private health insurance

  • benefiting from occupation-based insurance schemes reduce that likelihood

  • voluntary private health insurance reflects inequity in healthcare access

Advertisement

Conflict of interest

The author declares no conflict of interest.

Advertisement

Author funding

The author received no financial support for the research, authorship, and/or publication of this article.

Advertisement

Declaration

The author declares this work does not require any human/animal subjects to acquire ethical approval.

Advertisement

JEL classification

I13; D81; C3

References

  1. 1. Mossialos E, Thompson S. Report prepared for the Directorate General for Employment and Social Affairs of the European Commission. Brussels: European Commission; 2002
  2. 2. Eurostat. Eurostat Database. 2020. Available from: https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/data/database [Assessed: March 4, 2020]
  3. 3. Simoes J, Augusto GF, Fronteira I, Hernández-Quevedo C. Portugal: Health system review. Health Systems in Transition. 2017;19(2):1-184
  4. 4. Arrow K. Uncertainty and the welfare economics of medical care. The American Economic Review. 1963;53(5):941-973
  5. 5. Rothchild M, Stiglitz J. Equilibrium in competitive insurance markets: An essay on the economics of imperfect information. Quarterly Journal of Economics. 1976;90(4):629-649
  6. 6. Pauly MV. The economics of moral hazard: Comment. The American Economic Review. 1968;58(3):531-537
  7. 7. Akerlof GA. The market for lemons: Quality uncertainty and the market mechanism. QJ Econ. 1970;84(3):488-500
  8. 8. Hemenway D. Propitious selection. QJ Economics. 1990;105(4):1063-1069
  9. 9. Einav L, Finkelstein A, Levin J. Selection in insurance markets: Theory and empirics in pictures. The Journal of Economic Perspectives. 2011;25(1):115-138
  10. 10. Fang H, Keane M, Silverman D. Sources of Advantageous Selection: Evidence from the Meidgap Insurance Market. NBER Working Paper No. 12289; 2006
  11. 11. Bolhaar J, Lindeboom M, van der Klaauw B. A dynamic analysis of the demand for health insurance and health care. European Economic Review. 2012;56(4):669-690
  12. 12. Jones AM, Koolman X, Van Doorslaer E. The impact of having supplementary private health insurance on the use of specialists. Annales d’Economie et Statistique. 2006;83(84):251-275
  13. 13. Paccagnella O, Rebba V, Weber G. Voluntary private health insurance among the over 50s in Europe. Health Economics. 2012;22(3):289-315
  14. 14. Corea F. Big data and insurance: Advantageous selection in European Markets. Data Science Journal. 2017;16(33):1-15
  15. 15. Outreville JF. Risk aversion, risk behavior, and demand for insurance: A survey. Journal of Insurance Issues. 2014;37(4):158-186
  16. 16. Kiil A. What characterises the privately insured in universal health care system? A review of the empirical evidence. Health Policy. 2012;106:60-75
  17. 17. Sliwinski A, Borkowska I. Private Voluntary Health Insurance: Market in Poland and Determinants of Demand—Review of Literature. In: Janowicz-Lomott M, Lyskawa K, Plychronidou P, Karasavvoglou A, editors. Economic and Financial Challenges for Balkan and Eastern European Countries. Switzerland: Springer; 2020
  18. 18. Bolin K, Hedblom D, Lindgren A, Lindgren B. Asymmetric information and the demand for voluntary health insurance in Europe. NBER Working Paper. 2010:15689
  19. 19. Tavares AI. Voluntary private health insurance demand determinants and risk preferences: Evidence from SHARE. The International Journal of Health Planning and Management. 2019;2019:1-19
  20. 20. Oliveira M. Voluntary Health Insurance in Portugal: A Study for the European Commission. London: London School of Economics and Political Science; 2001
  21. 21. Propper C, Rees H, Green K. The demand for private medical insurance in the UK: A cohort analysis. The Econometrics Journal. 2001;111(471):180-200
  22. 22. Wagstaff A, van Doorslaer E. Measuring inequalities in health in the presence of multiple-category morbidity indicators. Health Economics. 1994;3:281-289
  23. 23. Doiron D, Jones G, Savage E. Healthy, wealthy and insured? The role of self-assessed health in the demand for private health insurance. Health Economics. 2008;17(3):317-334
  24. 24. Jofre-Bonet M. Public health care and private insurance demand: The waiting time as a link. Health Care Management Science. 2000;3:51-71
  25. 25. Johar M, Jones G, Keane M, Savage E, Stavrunova O. Waiting times and the decision to buy private health insurance. Working Paper 2010/9. Centre for Health Economics Research and Evaluation, University of Technology Sydney; 2010
  26. 26. De Meza D, Webb DC. Advantageous selection in insurance markets. The Rand Journal of Economics. 2001;32(2):249-262
  27. 27. Buchmueller TC, Couffinhal A, Grignon M, Perronnin M. Access to physician services: Does supplemental insurance matter? Evidence from France. Health Economics. 2004;13(7):669-687
  28. 28. Harmon C, Nolan B. Health insurance and health services utilization in Ireland. Health Economics. 2001;10(2):135-145
  29. 29. Schokkaert E, van Ourti T, de Graeve D, Lecluyse A, van de Voorde C. Supplemental health insurance and equality of access in Belgium. Health Economics. 2010;19:377-395
  30. 30. King D, Mossialos E. The determinants of private medical insurance prevalence in England, 1997-2001. Health Services Research. 2005;40(1):195-212
  31. 31. Costa J, Garcia J. Demand for private health insurance: How important is the quality gap? Health Economics. 2003;12:587-599
  32. 32. Saliba B, Ventelou B. Complementary health insurance in France. Who pays? Why? Who will suffer from public disengagement? Health Policy. 2007;81:166-182
  33. 33. Jerant A, Fiscella K, Franks P. Health characteristics associated with gaining and losing private and public health insurance: A national study. Medical Care. 2012;50(2):145-151
  34. 34. INE. National Health Survey. General information. 2014. Available from: https://www.ine.pt/xportal/xmain?xpid=INE&xpgid=ine_publicacoes&PUBLICACOESpub_boui=263714091&PUBLICACOESmodo=2&xlang=pt [Assessed: January 4, 2020]
  35. 35. Emmerson C et al. Should private medical insurance be subsidised? Health Care UK. 2001:49-65
  36. 36. Van De Ven W, Van Praag B. The demand for deductibles in private health insurance. Journal of Econometrics. 1981;17:229-252
  37. 37. Carvalho C, Manso AC, Escoval A, Salvado F, Nunes C. Self-perception of oral health in older adults from an urban population in Lisbon, Portugal. Revista de Saúde Pública. 2016;50:50-53
  38. 38. Kossioni AE. Is Europe prepared to meet the oral health needs of older people? Gerodontology. 2011;29(2):e1230-e1240
  39. 39. Propper C. Constrained choice sets in the UK demand for private medical insurance. Journal of Public Economics. 1993;51:287-307
  40. 40. Kahneman D, Tversky A. Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica. 1979;47:263-291

Written By

Aida Isabel Tavares

Submitted: 06 February 2022 Reviewed: 29 April 2022 Published: 31 May 2022