Open access peer-reviewed chapter

Modeling Bitcoin Price and Bubbles

Written By

Alessandra Cretarola and Gianna Figà-Talamanca

Submitted: 15 February 2018 Reviewed: 08 June 2018 Published: 05 November 2018

DOI: 10.5772/intechopen.79386

From the Edited Volume

Blockchain and Cryptocurrencies

Edited by Asma Salman and Muthanna G. Abdul Razzaq

Chapter metrics overview

2,021 Chapter Downloads

View Full Metrics

Abstract

The goal of this chapter is to present recent developments about Bitcoin1 price modeling and related applications. Precisely, we consider a bivariate model in continuous time to describe the behavior of Bitcoin price and of the investors’ attention on the overall network. The attention index affects Bitcoin price through a suitable dependence on the drift and diffusion coefficients and a possible correlation between the sources of randomness represented by the driving Brownian motions. The model is fitted on historical data of Bitcoin prices, by considering the total trading volume and the Google Search Volume Index as proxies for the attention measure. Moreover, a closed formula is computed for European-style derivatives on Bitcoin. Finally, we discuss two possible extensions of the model. Precisely, we investigate the relation between the correlation parameter and possible bubble effects in the asset price; further, we consider a multivariate framework to represent the special feature of Bitcoin being traded on several exchanges and we discuss conditions to rule out arbitrage opportunities in this setting.

Keywords

  • Bitcoin
  • market attention
  • arbitrage
  • option pricing
  • bubbles

1. Introduction

Bitcoin is a digital currency built on a peer-to-peer network and on the blockchain, a public ledger where all transactions are recorded and made available to all nodes. Opposite to traditional banking transactions, based on trust for counterparty, Bitcoin relies on cryptography and on a consensus protocol for the network. The entire system is founded on an open source software created in 2009 by a computer scientist known under the pseudonym Satoshi Nakamoto, whose identity is still unknown (see [1]). Hence, Bitcoin is an independent digital currency, not subject to the control of central authorities and without inflation; furthermore, transactions in the network are pseudonymous and irreversible.

Bitcoin and the underlying blockchain technology have gained much attention in the last few years. Research on Bitcoin often deals with cybersecurity and legitimacy issues such as the analysis of double spending possibilities and other cyber-threats; recently, high returns and volatility have attracted research toward the analysis of Bitcoin price efficiency as well as its dynamics (see, among others, [2, 3, 4]). Moreover, many contributions claim that Bitcoin price is driven by attention or sentiment about the Bitcoin system itself; see [5, 6, 7, 8]. Possible driving factors for the sentiment about the Bitcoin system are the volume of Google searches or Wikipedia requests as in [5], or more traditional indicators as the number or volume of transactions, as suggested in [6]. In [9], the author suggests a time series model in order to identify the dynamic relation between speculation activity and price.

In this chapter, after having introduced the basic concepts underlying Bitcoin, we sum up and describe to a broader audience the recent outcomes of the research reported in [10], by avoiding unnecessary technicalities. Some new insights are also given by looking at possible extensions in order to take into account the presence of bubble effects or the special feature of Bitcoin being traded in different online platforms (exchanges) that will be further investigated in our future research.

Advertisement

2. The Bitcoin network

We recall that Bitcoin was first introduced as an electronic payment system between peers by Satoshi Nakamoto (pseudonym) in [1]. Opposite to traditional transactions, which are based on the trust in financial intermediaries, this system relies on the network, on the fixed rules and on cryptography. Bitcoins can be purchased on appropriate websites that allow to change usual currencies in the cryptocurrency.

The Bitcoin network has several attractive properties for its users:

  • No central bank authority for money supply and no regulator;

  • Transactions are 24/7 and without any country border;

  • Transaction cost are almost negligible with respect to traded amount;

  • Transaction are anonymous;

  • The security of each transaction is guaranteed by cryptography and digital signature;

  • The security of the whole network is guaranteed by construction unless more than 50% of the network nodes agree on a deceptive action.

As a digital payment system, Bitcoins may be used to pay for several online services and goods. Special applications have been designed for smartphones and tablets for transactions in Bitcoins and some ATMs have appeared all over the world (see Coin ATM radar) to change traditional currencies in Bitcoins. Accepting Bitcoins as a payment method is also related to an advertisement opportunity for companies. However, the high returns achieved in the last few years have transformed Bitcoin in a speculative asset affecting its use as a form of payment.

The Bitcoin system has been subject to many cracks but has proven to be very resilient as the value of the cryptocurrency was able to rise again after all the falls. Nevertheless, at the time of writing, Bitcoin was experiencing a fall in its exchange rate with main fiat currencies.

Two of the main crackdowns were China enforcement in December 2013 and Mt. Gox bankruptcy in February 2014.

Besides technical and regulation issues, the Bitcoin system also faces reputational concerns.

In fact, the ambiguity of anonymous transactions has blamed the network of allowing several criminal activities such as buying illegal goods, money laundering or the financing of terrorism actions. As a representative example, we recall that The Silk Road was a website that started selling narcotics and illegal drugs in 2011, payable in Bitcoins. The website was finally shutdown by 2013 and the owner was arrested and sentenced to life in prison. Again, anonymous transactions make it possible to use huge quantities of money, exchanged in Bitcoins, without declaring its origin, hence allowing for possible money laundering. However, according to a research performed by the UK government, the highest score related to money laundering is still cash, followed by the bank, accountancy and legal service providers (see https://www.gov.uk/government/publications/uk-national-risk-assessment-of-money-laundering-and-terrorist-financing).

It is worth noticing that while counterparties are represented by secret addresses and are anonymous, all transactions are recorded and might be traced. Investigation is hence favored by this feature of the network.

Despite the flaws in the system, Bitcoin has achieved a notwithstanding rise in recent years.

In Figure 1, we report Bitcoin price and returns from January 2012 to December 2017 (source https://blockchain.info/en/charts).

Figure 1.

Bitcoin price (top) and returns (bottom) from January 2012 to December 2017.

Advertisement

3. An attention-based model

The model we suggest in what follows is motivated by findings in [5, 6, 8, 11] where it is showed that Bitcoin price is related to investors’ attention measured by the trading volume and/or the number of searches in engines such as Google and Wikipedia. Bitcoin is treated as a financial stock as suggested in [12] and the suggested model may be applied in principle to other assets that are proven to depend on market attention.

3.1. The model specification

Consider a probability space Ω F P endowed with a filtration F = F t t 0 satisfying usual assumptions of right continuity and completeness.

Let us denote the Bitcoin price process as S = S t t 0 and assume that it depends on an attention factor denoted by A = A t t 0 . The dynamics of the two processes are described by the following equation:

dS t S t = μ S A t dt + σ S A t dW t , S 0 = s 0 R + dA t = μ A A t dt + σ A A t dZ t , A 0 = a 0 R + , E1

where μ A , μ S , σ A > 0 , σ S > 0 are constant parameters and W Z = W t Z t t 0 is an F P -standard Brownian motion in R 2 . Assume that F t = σ W u Z u u t , for each t 0 .

It is well known that the above dynamics for the attention factor is a geometric Brownian motion, the solution of which is given by A t = A 0 exp μ A σ A 2 2 t + σ A Z t for t 0 which has a log-normal distribution; integrating the price process is straightforward to get

S t = S 0 exp μ S σ S 2 2 0 t A u du + σ S 0 t A u dW u , t 0 . E2

3.2. Statistical properties and model fitting

We collect in this subsection the properties of the logarithmic returns obtained by the price process defined in Eq. (1).

Consider the discrete process A S i = 1 2 n obtained by sampling the price process and the attention factor at times t i = , i = 1 , 2 , n with constant observation step Δ; denote the logarithmic changes of the process by R i = log S S i 1 Δ , P i = log A A i 1 Δ and define X i i 1 Δ A u du . Note that R i , i = 1 , 2 , n represent the logarithmic returns of asset S for the sampling dates and that X i , i = 1 , 2 , n the cumulative attention in the time interval [ i 1 Δ , ] . Then it is straightforward to prove the following:

Theorem 2.1. The random vector R = R 1 R 2 R n , given X = X 1 X 2 X n , is normally distributed with mean m and covariance matrix Σ where

m i = μ S σ S 2 2 X i , for i = 1 , 2 , n , Σ = Diag σ S 2 X 1 σ S 2 X 2 .. σ S 2 X n . E3

Proof. In order to prove the theorem it suffices to remind that, for i = 1, 2, …, n, the random variable i 1 Δ A u dW u , conditional on knowing X i , is normally distributed with zero mean and variance X i , and that the increments of the Brownian motion W are independent.

As for the unconditional distribution, it is easy to obtain, for i = 1 , 2 , , n ,

E R i = μ S σ S 2 2 E X i , Var R i = μ S σ S 2 2 2 Var X i + σ S 2 E X i , E4

where E X i , Var X i can be computed in closed form as a function of μ A , σ A , Δ (see for example [10]). The above outcomes are applied in order to derive the likelihood of the vector R X . Indeed, by simply applying Bayes’ rule, we get the following result:

Proposition 2.2. The joint probability density of the vector R X is given by g : R × R + R with

g r x = f X 1 x 1 i = 2 n f X i X i 1 x i i = 1 n 1 2 πσ S 2 x i exp r i μ S σ S 2 2 x i 2 σ S 2 x i , E5

where f X 1 and f X i X i 1 are the probability density function of X 1 and X i given X i 1 , respectively.

The proof follows from Bayes’ rule and application of Theorem 2.1.

It is worth to remark that the probability density g in Eq. (5) depends on suitable choices for f X 1 and f X i X i 1 . Under our assumptions, such densities are not given within known distribution; however, by applying outcomes in [13], we can approximate them as log-normals with means and variances given as closed expressions of μ A σ A .

Precisely, we have that f X 1 = LN α ν and, for i = 2 , 3 , n , f X i X i 1 = LN α i ν i , with

α 1 = log E X 1 2 E X 1 2 , ν 1 2 = log E X 1 2 E X 1 2 , α i = log X i 1 + μ A σ A 2 2 Δ , ν i 2 = σ A 2 Δ . E6

We apply the outcomes above in order to estimate model parameters according to the maximum-likelihood method (see for example [14, 15]) where the likelihood is approximated by applying the Levy approximation [13].

Parameter estimates are obtained as

μ ̂ A μ ̂ S σ ̂ A σ ̂ S = arg max μ A , μ S , σ A , σ S log μ A μ S σ A σ S r x , E7

where

log μ A μ S σ A σ S r x = i = 1 n log 1 2 π x i σ S 2 r i μ S σ S 2 2 x i 2 2 x i σ 2 S + i = 1 n log 1 x i 2 π v i 2 log x i α i 2 2 v i 2 E8

3.3. Empirical application on Bitcoin prices

The first step in our procedure is to identify possible measures of investors’ attention. As already mentioned in the introduction, we consider the total trading volume on Bitcoin available from https://blockchain.info as well as the search volume index (SVI) for Google searches on the topic “bitcoin” provided by https://trends.google.it/trends/.

The trading volume of exchange is a classical measure of the attractiveness of a traded asset for an investor; besides, in [16], the authors find evidence that the latter captures the attention of retail/uniformed investors.

We consider daily data from January 1, 2015, to June 30, 2017, for the total volume and the SVI Index. As for the daily value of the Bitcoin, we have considered the average mean across main exchanges represented by the Index in https://blockchain.info.

In Table 1, the outcomes for parameter estimates, obtained by maximizing the approximate likelihood given the observed time series, are summed up.

μ ̂ A σ ̂ A μ ̂ S σ ̂ S
A = Vol 0.9571 1.1346 0.0218 0.0829
A = SVI 1.3584 1.0687 0.0743 0.1559

Table 1.

Parameter estimates for the model in Eq. (1) fitted on daily observations from January 2015 to June 2017.

Advertisement

4. A closed formula for Bitcoin option prices

In this section, we show how to characterize the price of European call options on Bitcoins in the underlying market model. Let us fix a finite time horizon T > 0 and assume the existence of a riskless asset (also called the savings account), whose price process B = B t t 0 T is given by

B t = exp 0 t r s ds , t 0 T , E9

where r : 0 T R is a bounded, deterministic function representing the instantaneous risk-free interest rate. To be reasonable, the market model must avoid arbitrage opportunities, that is, investment strategies that do not require an initial investment and that do not expose to any risk and lead to a positive value with positive probability. From a mathematical point of view, this means to check that the set of equivalent martingale measures for the Bitcoin price process S is nonempty. Precisely, it is possible to prove that it contains more than a single element.

Lemma 3.1. Every equivalent martingale measure Q for S is characterized by its density process with respect to the initial probability measure P as follows:

dQ dP F t = exp 0 t μ S A u r u σ S A u dW u 0 t γ u dZ u 1 2 0 t μ S A u r u σ S A u 2 du 1 2 0 t γ u 2 du , E10

where γ = γ t t 0 T is an F -adapted process such that 0 T γ u 2 du < + , P -a.s.

The proof can be deduced from that of Lemma 1.4 in [10], where they also account for a possible delay between the attention factor and its effect on Bitcoin prices trend. The process γ can be interpreted as the risk perception associated to the future direction or future possible movements of the Bitcoin market. Since S is the only tradable asset, the risk perception is not fixed and this explains the nonuniqueness of the martingale measure Q in this market framework that turns out to be incomplete. Consequently, given any European-type contingent claim, it is not possible in general to find a self-financing strategy whose terminal value exactly replicates the payoff of the claim. We recall that the notion of completeness is related to the uniqueness of the martingale measure. Indeed, in complete markets, the no-arbitrage price of any derivative is uniquely determined by the unique martingale measure. On the other hand, in incomplete markets, we deal with a family of martingale measures and have at our disposal a set of possible prices, which are all compatible with the “no-arbitrage condition.” One common approach to option pricing in incomplete markets in the mathematical financial literature is to select one specific martingale measure (which can be also called pricing measure) under which the discounted traded assets are martingales and to compute option prices via expectation under this measure via risk-neutral evaluation formulas. One simple example of a candidate equivalent martingale measure is the so-called minimal martingale measure (see [17, 18]), which minimizes the relative entropy, of the objective measure P , with respect to any risk-neutral measure. In this setting, its economic interpretation is that agents do not wish to be compensated for the risk associated with the fluctuations of the stochastic attention factor, which corresponds to the hypothesis of [19] in the stochastic volatility framework. This is the probability measure which corresponds to the choice γ 0 in Eq. (10). Intuitively, under the minimal martingale measure, say P ̂ , the drift of the Brownian motion driving the Bitcoin price process is modified to make S an F -martingale, while the drift of the Brownian motion which is strongly orthogonal to S is not affected by the change measure from P to P ̂ . More precisely, by Girsanov’s theorem, the R 2 -valued process W ̂ Z ̂ = W ̂ t Z ̂ t t 0 T defined by

W ̂ t W t + 0 t μ S A u r u σ S A u du , Z ̂ t Z t , E11

is an F P ̂ -standard Brownian motion. Under any equivalent martingale measure, the discounted Bitcoin price process S ˜ = S ˜ t t 0 T given by S ˜ t S t B t , for each t 0 T behaves like a martingale. Precisely, on the probability space Ω F P ̂ , the pair S ˜ A has the following dynamics:

d S ˜ t = σ S A t S ˜ t d W ̂ t , S ˜ 0 = s 0 R + , dA t = μ A A t dt + σ A A t dZ t , A 0 = a 0 R + . E12

Equivalently, we can write the discounted Bitcoin price process S ˜ as

S ˜ t = s 0 exp σ S 0 t A u d W ̂ u σ S 2 2 0 t A u du , t 0 T . E13

Clearly, under the minimal martingale measure P ̂ , the Bitcoin price process S satisfies

dS t = r t S t dt + σ S A t S t d W ̂ t , S 0 = s 0 R + , E14

where r t is the risk-free interest rate at time t .

Remark 3.2. Note that, under any equivalent martingale measure that keeps the drift of the attention factor dynamics linear in A (in particular, under the minimal martingale measure), the model proposed in [10] nests the Hull-White stochastic volatility model, which corresponds to the particular case where σ S = 1 ; see [19]. Indeed, the authors only referred to a risk-neutral framework without describing the dynamics under the physical measure and consequently characterizing the existence of any equivalent martingale measure.

Now, we compute the fair price of a Bitcoin European call option via the risk-neutral evaluation approach, so it can be expressed as expected value of the terminal payoff under the selected pricing measure, that is, the minimal martingale measure. Let CT = (STK)+ be the F T -measurable random variable representing the payoff of a European call option on the Bitcoin with price S with date of maturity T and strike price K , which can be traded on the underlying digital market. Recall that X t , T = X T X t , for each t 0 T , refers to the variation of the integrated attention process X defined over the interval t T . Then, denote by E P ̂ F t the conditional expectation with respect to the σ -field F t under the probability measure P ̂ and so on. Define the function C BS : 0 T × R + × R + R as follows:

C BS t s x s N d 1 t s x Ke 0 t r u du N d 2 t s x , E15

where

d 1 t s x = log s K + 0 t r u du + σ S 2 2 x σ S x E16

and d 2 t s x = d 1 t s x σ S x , or more explicitly

d 2 t s x = log s K + 0 t r u du σ S 2 2 x σ S x . E17

Here, N stands for the standard Gaussian cumulative distribution function, that is,

N y = 1 2 π y e z 2 2 dz , y R . E18

The following result provides the risk-neutral price of the option under the minimal martingale measure P ̂ . The proof is straightforward and may be derived by using similar arguments to those developed in [19].

Proposition 3.3. The risk-neutral price C t at time t of a European call option written on the Bitcoin with price S expiring in T and with strike price K is given by the formula

C t = E P ̂ C BS t S t X t , T S t = S t 0 + N d 1 t S t x f X t , T x dx Ke t T r u du 0 + N d 2 t S t x f X t , T x dx , E19

where the function C BS is defined in Eq. (15); the functions d 1 , d 2 are, respectively, given in Eqs. (16)-(17); and f X t , T denotes the density function of X t , T , for each t 0 T , provided that it exists.

Hence, the resulting risk-neutral pricing formula when evaluated in S t corresponds to the expected value of Black & Scholes price as defined in [20] at time t 0 T of a European call option written on S , with strike price K and maturity T , in a financial market where the volatility is random and given by σ S X t , T T t .

4.1. A numerical application

In order to appreciate the performance of the pricing formula in Eq. (19), we compute model prices for option traded on the online platform http://www.deribit.com on July, 30, 2017, by plugging in the estimated parameters. The outcomes are compared with the Black & Scholes benchmark (see [20]) as a reference price, computed by plugging the volatility parameter estimated on the same time series of the trading volume/SVI index, and with the bid-ask prices provided in the website. Best overall pricing values are obtained when market attention is measured by volume; in the case of the SVI Google index, near-term options are very close to the mid-value of the bid-ask, while next-term options are overpriced. One possible explanation is that investors that get information about Bitcoin on search engines are more likely to be uninformed/retail investors that are self-exciting and may add spurious noise to the Bitcoin price volatility leading to an increase in call option prices (Table 2).

T-K Market bid Market ask Model volume Model Google SVI Benchmark BS
Aug-2200 0.1662 0.2318 0.2029 0.2282 0.1967
Aug-2300 0.1670 0.2072 0.1737 0.2032 0.1655
Aug-2400 0.1390 0.1845 0.1469 0.1802 0.1369
Aug-2500 0.1142 0.1638 0.1228 0.1591 0.1112
Aug-2600 0.0922 0.1376 0.1014 0.1399 0.0887
Aug-2700 0.0749 0.1202 0.0828 0.1226 0.0695
Aug-2800 0.0572 0.1047 0.0684 0.107 0.0535
Aug-2900 0.0442 0.0983 0.0549 0.0931 0.0405
Sept-2200 0.1991 0.2648 0.2546 0.3204 0.2173
Sept-2300 0.1766 0.2432 0.2321 0.3019 0.1906
Sept-2400 0.1890 0.2230 0.2113 0.2844 0.1662
Sept-2500 0.1375 0.2042 0.1919 0.2679 0.1439
Sept-2600 0.1207 0.1828 0.1741 0.2523 0.1239
Sept-2700 0.1120 0.1668 0.1576 0.2377 0.1060
Sept-2800 0.0953 0.1504 0.1463 0.2239 0.0903
Sept-2900 0.0848 0.1422 0.1325 0.2109 0.0764

Table 2.

Comparison between model prices computed according to formula in Eq. (19), Black & Scholes formula in [20], and the bid and ask prices provided in http:\\www.deribit.comfor options traded on July, 30, 2017, and expiring on August 25, 2017, and on September 28, 2017.

Advertisement

5. The presence of model stock bubbles

Motivated by empirical evidences (see for example [21, 22]), we discuss a generalization of the model introduced in Section 3.1, which is capable to describe speculative bubbles in Bitcoin markets.

Precisely, we fix a finite time horizon T > 0 and assume that the underlying Brownian motions W and Z are correlated with constant correlation coefficient ρ 1 1 , that is, < W , Z > t = ρt for each t 0 T . If V = V t t 0 T is an additional F P -Brownian motion that is P -independent of Z , then we can write

W t = ρ Z t + 1 ρ 2 V t , t 0 T . E20

Without loss of generality, we assume that the interest rate is fixed and equal to zero. In this setting, the discounted Bitcoin price trend and the market attention factor dynamics are described by

dS t = μ S A t S t dt + σ S A t S t ρ dZ t + ρ ¯ dV t , S 0 = s 0 R + , dA t = μ A A t dt + σ A A t dZ t , A 0 = a 0 R + , E21

where we have set ρ ¯ 1 ρ 2 . The aim is to investigate the existence of asset-price bubbles in the underlying Bitcoin market model.

By simulating trajectories for the asset price S according to the model in Eq. (1) for several values of the correlation parameter, it seems that the latter is related to the presence of bubble effect; in fact, in Figure 2, we plot examples of trajectories for ρ = 0 , 0.5 , 0.5 , 1 , respectively where higher positive values for the correlation appear to boost the asset value.

Figure 2.

Simulated trajectories with n = 250 daily observations for the attention process (red) and the corresponding Bitcoin price dynamics for ρ = 0 (black), ρ = 0.5 (green), and ρ = 1 (blue).

Indeed, we will show formally that the possibility of Bitcoin speculative bubbles is related to the sign of the correlation parameter ρ .

The mathematical theory of financial bubbles is developed, among others, in [23, 24, 25]. Precisely, we introduce the following definition from [23].

Definition 4.1. The Bitcoin price process S has a bubble on the time interval 0 T if S is a strict F -local martingale under the chosen risk-neutral measure.

The term strict F -local martingale refers to the fact that S is an F -local martingale, but not a true F -martingale under the chosen risk-neutral measure. Further, since S is nonnegative, we must have that S is an F -supermartingale (we refer to [26] for rigorous definitions and related concepts).

Recall that the absence of arbitrage opportunities is “essentially” equivalent to the existence of a probability measure Q , equivalent to the initial probability P , under which the discounted price process satisfies the martingale property.

Remark 4.2. Note that stock bubbles arise if S has an equivalent local martingale measure but not an equivalent martingale measure. Arbitrage appears only if no equivalent local martingale measure exists.

Then, to exclude arbitrage opportunities from the market, we define the process L = L t t 0 T by setting

L t dQ dP F t = exp 0 t λ u dV u 1 2 0 t λ u 2 du 0 t γ u dZ u 1 2 0 t γ u 2 du , t 0 T , E22

where λ = λ t t 0 T and γ = γ t t 0 T are F -adapted processes satisfying the integrability conditions 0 T λ u 2 du < P -a.s. and 0 T γ u 2 du < P -a.s., respectively. The (local) martingale property of the discounted Bitcoin price process S under Q implies the following condition:

μ S A t = σ S A t λ t ρ ¯ + γ t ρ , t 0 T , P a . s . . E23

To ensure that L provides the density process of a probability measure equivalent to P , we require that E L T = 1 , meaning that L is an F P -martingale. The processes λ and γ are interpreted, respectively, as the risk premium and the risk perception associated to the future direction or future possible movements of the Bitcoin market. For each choice of the process γ , the process λ is fixed by Eq. (23), that is,

λ t = 1 ρ ¯ μ S A t σ S ργ t , t 0 T , E24

and we can consider the corresponding family of equivalent (local) martingale measures Q γ for S parameterized by the process γ . To check if there are stock bubbles in the underlying market model, we study under which conditions the discounted Bitcoin price is a strict F P -local martingale with respect to an equivalent local martingale measure Q γ . By applying Girsanov’s theorem, the dynamics of the model under Q γ is described by the following equations:

dS t = σ S A t S t ρd Z ˜ t + ρ ¯ d V ˜ t , S 0 = s 0 R + , dA t = μ A σ A γ t A t dt + σ A A t d Z ˜ t , A 0 = a 0 R + , E25

where the R 2 -valued process V ˜ Z ˜ = V ˜ t Z ˜ t t 0 T defined by V ˜ t V t + 0 t λ u du , .

Z ˜ t Z t + 0 t γ u du , is an F Q γ -standard Brownian motion.

Now, suppose that the risk perception process is zero, that is, γ 0 . Then, the change of measure from P to Q 0 is well-defined since the associated density process M = M t t 0 T satisfying

dM t = μ S ρ ¯ σ S A t M t dV t , M 0 = 1 , dA t = μ A A t dt + σ A A t dZ t , A 0 = a 0 . E26

is a true F P -martingale thanks to [27]. We have the following result, which allows to detect the presence of bubbles in this setting.

Proposition 4.3. In the model outlined in Eq. (24), the Bitcoin price process S has a bubble on 0 T if and only if ρ > 0 .

The proof is based on the application of some of Sin’s results given in [27], where the existence of risk-neutral measures for the Hull-White stochastic volatility model [19] and for similar frameworks is determined by the possibility of explosion in finite time for solutions of certain auxiliary stochastic differential equations. Precisely, it is possible to show that the martingale property of the discounted stock price S under Q 0 , given in Eq. (25) with γ = 0 , is fulfilled if and only if ρ 0 . Hence, a bubble arises if and only if the correlation parameter between stock returns and market attention is positive.

Advertisement

6. Toward a multiexchange generalization

Let us generalize the model introduced in Eq. (1) by assuming a possible delay τ for the attention factor to affect the Bitcoin price dynamics. Assume that the attention factor has been observed or is described by a deterministic function for t l 0 with l τ . We get

dS t S t = μ S A t τ dt + σ S A t τ dW t , S 0 = s 0 R + , dA t = μ P A t dt + σ A A t dZ t , A t = φ t for t l 0 , E27

where φ : l 0 R + .

Analogous results as those in Section 2 can be derived by similar computations, and model parameters, for a fixed delay, can be estimated by means of the maximum likelihood method. In order to estimate the delay parameter, we maximize the profile likelihood as defined in [15]. Details of this procedure can be found in [10]. The estimation results of model in Eq. (27) on the same daily data considered in Section 2 are summed up in Table 3.

τ μ ̂ A σ ̂ A μ ̂ S σ ̂ S
A = Vol 1 day 0.4881 1.0459 0.0282 0.0924
A = SVI 7 days 1.0964 0.9946 0.1005 0.1885

Table 3.

Parameter estimates for model in Eq. (27) fitted on daily observations from January 2015 to June 2017.

In Figure 3, we plot simulated trajectories of the price process in Eq. (27) by letting the delay parameter vary.

Figure 3.

Simulated trajectories of n = 250 daily observations of the attention factor (red) and the Bitcoin price according to model in Eq. (27) when the delay parameter is τ = 1 day (black) and τ = 10 days (blue).

The different delays result in a shift to the south-east between the faster and slower reacting trajectories; in the picture, this behavior is sharp since the other model parameters are kept constant. By looking at the picture, the idea to model the price of Bitcoin in different exchanges by the same model in Eq. (27) but allowing different parameters naturally arises.

In particular, considering for instance two exchanges, we have

dS t 1 S t 1 = μ S 1 A t τ 1 dt + σ S 1 A t τ 1 dW t , S 0 1 = s 0 1 R + , dS t 2 S t 2 = μ S 2 A t τ 2 dt + σ S 2 A t τ 2 dW t , S 0 2 = s 0 2 R + , dA t = μ A A t dt + σ A A t dZ t , A t = φ t for t l 0 , E28

where φ : l 0 R + with l > max τ 1 τ 2 and μ A i , μ S i , σ A i > 0 , σ S i > 0 for i = 1, 2 are constant parameters.

Note that within this model, prices for Bitcoin traded in different exchanges are perfectly correlated. Indeed, this is what happens in observed data; considering daily prices from January 2015 to June 2017 for Bitstamp, Kraken, Cex.io, Gdax, and The Rock exchanges we get cross-correlation values larger than 0.999.

We fit model in Eq. (28) for the Bitstamp and Gdax exchanges on daily observations of Bitcoin price from January 2015 to June 2017 obtaining the outcomes reported in Table 4, when the attention is measured by the trading volume, and in Table 5, when attention is measured by the Google SVI index.

Exchange τ μ A σ A μ S σ S
Bitstamp 1 0.4994 1.0461 0.0281 0.0896
Gdax 2 0.4997 1.0420 0.0326 0.1036

Table 4.

Model fitting with delay parameter: outcomes for Bitstamp and Gdax exchanges when attention is measured by the trading volume.

Exchange τ μ A σ A μ S σ S
Bitstamp 7 days 1.0934 0.9946 0.0992 0.1782
Gdax 7 days 1.0964 0.9946 0.1160 0.2087

Table 5.

Model fitting with delay parameter: outcomes for Bitstamp and Gdax exchanges when attention is measured by the SVI index.

It is evident from the outcomes in Table 4 that the model parameters are not significantly different while the delay might be quite different as if the reaction to the attention factor is faster for some exchanges and slower for others. On the contrary, when attention is measured by the Google SVI Index, the delay is unchanged, but the difference between estimated parameters for the price dynamics is nonnegligible.

By analyzing the outcomes and considering the shift effect as depicted in Figure 3, it is tempting to conjecture that the faster reaction determines the leader exchanges and that the slower exchange will then follow. If we could forecast that the next day price of the slower exchange will reach the price today for the faster one, we could obtain a profit by suitably investing in the two exchanges. However, it is worth noticing that the estimation of the delay parameter is obtained by maximizing the likelihood over a whole time series and is a product of averaging so arbitrage cannot be achieved in a direct way.

Nevertheless, in a multivariate setting as ours, the theory guarantees that arbitrage opportunities are ruled out if the market price of risk in the market is unique. Without entering technical details and assuming r = 0 for the sake of simplicity, this is true if and only if

μ S 1 σ S 1 A t τ 1 = μ S 2 σ S 2 A t τ 2 , t 0 . E29

It is evident that these values are not equal if we plug parameter estimates in Eq. (30); hence, arbitrage opportunities are not ruled out at least from a theoretical point of view. We will address this issue more precisely in future research.

Advertisement

7. Conclusion

In this chapter, we have introduced a model in continuous time in order to describe the dynamics of Bitcoin price depending on an exogenous stochastic factor, which represents market attention on the Bitcoin system. Market attention is measured either by the total trading volume in Bitcoins or by means of the Google Search Volume Index, which, as suggested in [16], is a direct measure of the revealed attention for uniformed retail investors. More precisely, the attention factor affects directly the instantaneous mean and volatility of logarithmic returns; in addition, it may be also correlated with the price changes. An estimation procedure to fit the model to observed data is also suggested and, under the assumption of no correlation, a closed formula for standard European option prices on Bitcoin is provided.

By applying outcomes within the mathematical theory of bubbles [23, 24, 25, 27], we are able to show that Bitcoin boosts in a bubble if and only if there is a positive correlation between changes in the price and in the attention factor. This finding is reasonable and claims that a stronger positive dependence between the two processes in Eq. (21) may result in an explosion of the price process.

Finally, we allow for a delay on the effect of market attention on the Bitcoin price, and, based on this generalized model, we introduce a multivariate setting for our model (Eq. (28)) in order to take into account the special feature of multiple exchanges where it is possible to trade in Bitcoins. Preliminary results indicate that arbitrage opportunities may arise in two exchanges that are characterized by different delays.

Advertisement

Acknowledgments

We gratefully acknowledge Marco Patacca for having provided the routines in Matlab® to develop the empirical sections of the paper and for useful suggestions and comments. We also acknowledge funding from Fondazione Cassa di Risparmio di Perugia (Grant 2015:0459013) and Bank of Italy (Grant 407660/16).

Advertisement

Conflict of interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Advertisement

Thanks

Gianna Figà-Talamanca gratefully acknowledges interesting discussions on the topic of this chapter with colleagues of the Department of Finance and Risk Engineering where she was visiting professor while preparing this research. The authors also wish to thank Stefano Bistarelli for having introduced them to the intriguing and worth to explore world of cryptocurrencies.

References

  1. 1. Nakamoto S. Bitcoin: A Peer-To-Peer Electronic Cash System. 2009. http://www.Bitcoin.org
  2. 2. Urquhart A. The inefficiency of bitcoin. Economics Letters. 2016;148:80-82
  3. 3. Dyhrberg AO. Bitcoin, gold and the dollar–A garch volatility analysis. Finance Research Letters. 2016;16:85-92
  4. 4. Katsiampa P. Volatility estimation for bitcoin: A comparison of garch models. Economics Letters. 2017;158:3-6
  5. 5. Kristoufek L. BitCoin meets Google trends and Wikipedia: Quantifying the relationship between phenomena of the internet era. Scientific Reports. 2013;3(3415):1-7
  6. 6. Kristoufek L. What are the main drivers of the bitcoin price? Evidence from wavelet coherence analysis. PLoS One. 2015;10(4):e0123923
  7. 7. Bukovina J, Marticek M. Sentiment and bitcoin volatility. Technical report, Mendel University in Brno, Faculty of Business and Economics; 2016
  8. 8. Figà-Talamanca G, Patacca M. Does market attention affect Bitcoin returns and volatility? SSRN Electronic Journal. 2018:11
  9. 9. Blau BM. Price dynamics and speculative trading in bitcoin. Research in International Business and Finance. 2017;41:493-499
  10. 10. Cretarola A, Figà-Talamanca G, Patacca M. Market Attention and Bitcoin Price Modeling: Theory, Estimation and Option Pricing. Submitted; 2018
  11. 11. Kim YB, Lee SH, Kang SJ, Choi MJ, Lee J, Kim CH. Virtual world currency value fluctuation prediction system based on user sentiment analysis. PLoS One. 2015;10(8):e0132944
  12. 12. Yermack D. Is bitcoin a real currency? An economic appraisal. In: Handbook of Digital Currency. USA: Academic Press; 2015. pp. 31-43
  13. 13. Levy E. Pricing European average rate currency options. Journal of International Money and Finance. 1992;11(5):474-491
  14. 14. Davison AC. Statistical Models, Volume 11. USA: Cambridge University Press; 2003
  15. 15. Pawitan Y. In all Likelihood: Statistical Modelling and Inference Using Likelihood. UK: Oxford University Press; 2001
  16. 16. Da Z, Engelberg J, Gao P. In search of attention. The Journal of Finance. 2011;66(5):1461-1499
  17. 17. Föllmer H, Schweizer M, Hedging of contingent claims under incomplete information. In M.H.A Davis and R.J.Elliot, editors, Applied Stochastic Analysis. New York, Gordon and Breach. 1991;5:389‐414
  18. 18. Föllmer H, Schweizer M. Minimal martingale measure. In: Encyclopedia of Quantitative Finance. Wiley Online Library; 2010
  19. 19. Hull J, White A. The pricing of options on assets with stochastic volatilities. The Journal of Finance. 1987;42(2):281-300
  20. 20. Black F, Scholes M. The pricing of options and corporate liabilities. The Journal of Political Economy. 1973:81(3):637-654
  21. 21. Malhotra A, Maloo M. Bitcoin–Is it a bubble? Evidence from unit root tests. SSRN Electronic Journal. 2014:13
  22. 22. Corbet S, Lucey B, Yarovya L. Datestamping the Bitcoin and Ethereum bubbles. Finance Research Letters. 2017:8 (In press)
  23. 23. Jarrow RA, Protter PE, Shimbo K. Asset price bubbles in incomplete markets. Mathematical Finance. 2010;20(2):145-185
  24. 24. Protter PE. A mathematical theory of financial bubbles. In: Paris-Princeton Lectures on Mathematical Finance. Switzerland: Springer; 2013. pp. 1-108
  25. 25. Protter PE. Bubbles and crashes - mathematical models of bubbles. Quantitative Finance Letters. 2016;4:10-13
  26. 26. Protter PE. Stochastic Integration and Differential Equations. Germany: Springer; 2005
  27. 27. Sin CA. Complications with stochastic volatility models. Advances in Applied Probability. 1998;30(1):256-268

Notes

  • We use the following rule throughout the paper: the term BitCoin refers to the whole system network while Bitcoin refers to the digital currency.

Written By

Alessandra Cretarola and Gianna Figà-Talamanca

Submitted: 15 February 2018 Reviewed: 08 June 2018 Published: 05 November 2018