Open access peer-reviewed chapter

Carbon Sequestration as a Land Management Strategy

Written By

Carianne Johnson

Submitted: 02 August 2023 Reviewed: 09 August 2023 Published: 13 November 2023

DOI: 10.5772/intechopen.112858

From the Edited Volume

Land-Use Management - Recent Advances, New Perspectives, and Applications

Edited by Sérgio António Neves Lousada

Chapter metrics overview

53 Chapter Downloads

View Full Metrics

Abstract

Carbon sequestration mechanisms were developed as a land management strategy in the AFOLU sector. The principal land management strategies to obtain payment for ecosystem services include afforestation and restoration, soil carbon sequestration and bioenergy. Improvements in land management can then be traded for payments in two mechanisms—the compliance carbon market and voluntary carbon market. While the compliance market focuses on reducing carbon emissions at the national level in accordance with international agreements the voluntary markets have a multi-level focus working not only with governments but also emphasizes direct engagement with private sector to achieve global emission reduction goals. Each mechanism’s structure has benefits and drawbacks with one key shortcoming in both—the access to funding for communities reliant on forest ecosystems which directly impacts the effectiveness of the mechanism to improve land management.

Keywords

  • AFOLU
  • carbon markets
  • land management
  • rural development
  • carbon rights

1. Introduction

Carbon sequestration is the process of storing carbon. Forests sequester carbon by retaining carbon through the soils, woody debris, litter and biomass [1]. Initially research that determined the carbon sequestration potential of soil, woody debris, litter and biomass was very intensive and time consuming, namely laboratory examinations of soil samples [2, 3, 4]. To address this, allometric equations were developed to be less time consuming and included calculations based on the diameter at breast height, crown diameter, tree height, tree species [5]. Obtaining forest inventory data of different tree species became the primary method to determine carbon stocks and once inventory data was collected consistently changes in the carbon stock of the forest were quickly determined [6, 7].

In an effort to reduce the greenhouse gases (GHGs) in the atmosphere several global mechanisms were developed to ‘offset’ the GHGs emissions by preserving forests [8]. A carbon offset is measured in tons of carbon dioxide (tCO2e) and is defined by [9, 10] as the amount of carbon sequestration or emission reduction of carbon dioxide. Carbon offsets are quantifiable units of GHG reductions [11] ‘traded’ through a cap-and-trade program where carbon emissions in the developed countries are offset by carbon sequestration efforts in the developing countries. Each cap-and-trade program determines a set amount of emissions allowed which is known as the cap and in order to prevent the emissions from exceeding the prescribed cap, companies offset their emissions by investing in programs that sequester carbon through carbon market trading.

There are two types of carbon markets to date compliance and the voluntary market. These mechanisms were originally envisioned under the Kyoto Protocol which allowed for countries to develop cap-and-trade programs and offset their emissions. Developing countries committed to preserving their ecosystems with carbon sequestration potential while developed countries committed to developing cap-and-trade programs to offset their emissions [12]. Cap-and-trade programs were not developed by all countries, so the Paris agreement extended the requirements of reducing global emissions and requested for all signing parties to outline their emission reduction goals in the National Determined Contributions (NDC). The compliance mechanisms developed were not easily accepted and did not provide the expected impetus for global emission reductions. The effectiveness of the carbon markets continues to be the focus of debate as the cap-and-trade structure allows for buyers to obtain carbon offsets to keep their emissions within allowable limits [12]. The carbon offsets are then seen as licenses to continue business as usual. While some developed countries have national cap-and-trade programs, others only have regional/state-based programs. Existing programs have stark differences allowing for discrepancies in emissions CAPs and acceptable methods for trading on carbon offsets [12, 13]. Additionally, structures for engaging in carbon trading are very cumbersome and require extensive time and technical acumen to receive verifiable credits that would be utilized in trading.

Concurrently, the voluntary mechanisms focused on engaging the private sector to develop emissions reductions commitments and offset their emissions through directly investing in carbon sequestration projects and programs [12]. The voluntary market is seen as the commodification of emissions that favor the companies with the resources to purchase the trades and therefore determine the demand of the credits [14, 15]. Market driven incentives are then unable to produce equitable and ecological results for communities reliant on forest resources [16, 17, 18, 19, 20]. However stronger regulation in the voluntary market could alienate small business and forest dependent communities that lack the resources to monitor and report their emission reductions using time consuming methodologies with extensive technical requirements [21, 22, 23, 24, 25, 26].

Advertisement

2. Carbon sequestration strategies in AFOLU sector

In the AFOLU sector there are a few principal strategies for reducing emissions and removing emissions. These strategies rely heavily on the science of carbon sequestration. The following is by no means a comprehensive list but provides an overview of the widely recognized strategies that are utilized to improve land management.

2.1 Afforestation or restoration

Afforestation and restoration (AR) is most widely utilized strategy of the list and is defined as conversion of non-forest land to forest through planting and seeding [27]. According to the Clean Development Mechanism (CDM) afforestation applies when the land was not forested for 50 years whereas reforestation applies to land that did not contain forest before 1990 [27, 28]. Assisted Natural Regeneration (ANR) also applies to this category. It is important to note that afforestation and restoration does not stipulate a time frame for the forest cover to be maintained only that a forest must have a crown cover greater than 105 [27, 28].

However, planting and seeding for mono or multi-species plantations also apply to this category. Plantations that are planted after cutting forests would not be considered in this category unless the plantation was established on grasslands, agricultural croplands or degraded forests with less than 10% crown/canopy cover [27, 29, 30].

Wetland restoration is the most significant aspect of AR due to the enhanced carbon sequestration of mangroves through their extensive root structures and soil composition [8]. This strategy is very variable due to the climate, geomorphology, relative sea level rise, wave energy and anthropogenic factors impacting a wetland system [8]. Wetland restoration requires more extensive assessments of conditions and tends to benefit from ANR activities versus human induced planting and seeding [8, 27]. Primary forests are more effective at sequestering carbon due to the age of the trees and their uninterrupted growth while afforestation and restoration activities require time to allow the forest to regenerate. This strategy is effective at reducing carbon emissions for extended periods and has even prompted countries to grow secondary forests in areas cleared for agricultural production. Agroforestry is also a practice that applies to this category allowing for agricultural production under the forest canopy. As a land management strategy carbon trading for AR projects and programs continues to be a substantial contributor to both the compliance and voluntary markets.

2.2 Soil carbon sequestration

Given the carbon sequestration potential of soil, cultivation practices can contribute to the release of carbon into the atmosphere and the loss of soil organic carbon [31]. Soil organic carbon is beneficial to promote stability in the soil and suppress the proliferation of diseases [32]. Soil carbon sequestration activities include the reducing tillage, green manuring through the use of tree litter, organic fertilizers as noted in [33, 34, 35]. While the strategy is effective at community and regional levels the global potential for sequestration has been subject to scrutiny particularly in agricultural settings [36, 37]. Soil organic carbon stocks are not only vulnerable to agricultural activities, it is also vulnerable to climate change through heterotrophic respiration [38, 39, 40, 41, 42, 43, 44] and are dependent on time and scale [38, 45, 46, 47].

However, carbon trading for soil carbon sequestration activities is widely utilized by the agricultural sector and benefits individual farm holders with additional financing to support their sustainable agriculture practices.

2.3 Bioenergy and biochar

Biochar is the conversion of biomass or plant material into charcoal through pyrolysis—the heating of the biomass material until the charcoal is formed [48]. During the process of developing biochar the gases are captured and condensed into liquid fuels namely bio-diesel and ethanol [48]. This process reduces emissions by using agricultural waste to create clean energy resulting in a carbon dense product that can be used with compost as fertilizer [48]. With an increase in demand for biofuels as a form of clean energy, the process of using plant material for energy has increased the use of land for crop plantations namely soy for bio-diesel and corn for ethanol [48, 49, 50]. Carbon offsets are traded for the creation of bio-energy and bio-char and the bio-energy created from agricultural waste provides greater opportunities for emission reduction [48, 50, 51].

Utilizing agricultural waste allows for combination of the three aforementioned strategies for overall ecosystem protection. Commercial production of bio-energy is also possible in agroforestry systems. However, land management practices that combine afforestation and reforestation, soil carbon sequestration and bioenergy production are only viable at limited landscape scales. On a commercial scale, there is the challenge of maintaining soil quality versus utilizing agricultural wastes for bio-energy [50, 51]. Emission reduction, land management strategies are feasible for rural, forest dependent communities to develop and maintain. This drives the popularity of these strategies in AFOLU sector for carbon trading and they can be traded in the compliance and voluntary market through different mechanisms.

Advertisement

3. Compliance carbon market mechanisms

Under the compliance market there are multiple mechanisms, however two of them are noteworthy. The Clean Development Mechanism (CDM) whose purpose is to support countries in meeting their sustainable development goals and achieve their reduction commitments [52]. There is continued optimism that the potential investment created from the CDM projects can directly support rural, forest dependent communities once the right structures and incentives are created [52, 53, 54]. For example, under the CDM-AR projects support the adoption of agroforestry in small holder farms as a way of engaging small holder farmers [54]. However, in forest dependent communities with unequal or unresolved tenure rights and direct access to the benefits of the projects remains a key concern [52, 53, 54]. Additionally, CDM structure and process for project development is managed by a board. The board are elected by parties to the Kyoto Protocol and they oversee the CDM process [55]. The process includes assessing projects, registering projects, issuing credits to registered projects, Additionally the board approves new methodologies, adopt new CDM rules and supervise the accreditation of independent auditing firms. Developing a project under the CDM must provide detailed information on the technologies employed, the expected impacts and calculation of the projected emission reductions using one the 140 methodologies in the CDM library [55]. While new methodologies can be proposed their approval relies on a review process though different groups—the UNFCCC secretariat, independent experts, and CDM methodology panel and the board which extends the process taken to get the project approved [55]. Once a project proposal has been reviewed it then needs to be validated by an independent auditor who then determines if the project follows all the CDM requirements [55]. Once the project is cleared by the auditor it goes into a 30-day public comment period where stakeholders can provide comments on the project. After the public comment period the auditor completes a report with recommendations on how to proceed with the project [55]. In addition to the auditor the CDM Board registration and issuance team reviews the project and provides recommendations. In the event that the two assessment differ the final decision to approve and register or reject the project is in the hands of the full board of the CDM [55]. If the project is approved, they can move forward with implementation.

However, the creation of tradable units or credits for the emissions reductions do not happen right away [55]. A second auditor, different from the one hired previously is required to verify the number of emission reductions which typically happens after 1 year of the project being in operation. The reports from the project activity are known as monitoring reports and they are then used to verify the emission reductions [55]. The auditor must verify that the project contributes to emissions reductions. Another board approval is needed to allow for CERs (CDM credits) to be issued to the project. When the CERs are issued then they can be traded. Credits are issued every monitoring period under the CDM system every 7 years [55]. There is the opportunity to apply for two 7-year renewals for credits to be issued or a 10-year non-renewable [55].

The process for CDM credits is long and rigorous requiring multiple approvals from the CDM board committees, auditors and engagement with national agencies and local stakeholders. Projects rejected by CDM struggled to provide a strong case for additionality—the case that the reduction of emissions would not have occurred with the sale of the credits of the proposed carbon project and incorrect use of the methodologies to determine the accurate emissions [56]. CDM has diverse interpretations of sustainable development that results in low standard assessment criteria for monitoring [56, 57]. In this case countries have not comprehensively developed monitoring systems to ensure that projects are achieving sustainable benefits. This impacts the quantity and quality of project benefits to forest dependent communities leaving developers to focus solely on the emission reductions aspects of the projects over the sustainable development benefits to these communities [58]. CDM also does not monetary incentives to benefit these communities and depends on the gaps to be filled by voluntary action on the part of the project developers or national agencies involved in the project [56, 59]. Under CDM projects that generate large volumes of CERs with low implementation costs are favored even as their projects generate no to very low benefits to communities reliant on forest resources [59].

The reducing emissions from deforestation and forest degradation in developing countries (REDD) mechanism sought to improve upon the shortcomings of CDM by emphasizing sustainable forest management of forests as a plus to mechanism [60]. REDD+ outlines how countries must use payments to reduce emissions through sustainable forest management and improved forest protection [60, 61]. A key component of REDD+ projects is the requirement of strategies that support national land-use and forest sector planning, stakeholder negotiations to determine provision of funds and services to local actors, carbon brokering and national level carbon accounting [61, 62, 63]. An integrated national approach is a key indication of the success of a REDD+ project giving principal responsibility for forest management to national governments [61, 62, 63]. Unlike CDM, not all REDD+ facilities require the generation of tradable units and the corresponding creation of registries, verification requirements and stringent rules for accounting [14, 64, 65, 66, 67, 68, 69, 70]. These transactions that do not meet carbon-market standards and would require additional structure to develop tradable offsets. Action for ERR issued under REDD+ to become legally defined certificates will allow for an established registry to track transfers of the offset [71]. The one facility under REDD+ mechanism that requires tradable units is the World Bank’s Forest Carbon Partnership Facility (FCPF). This facility precisely outlines the activities that contribute to sustainable forest management namely improving forest law management, strengthening protected areas network, direct payments for environmental services, reduced impact logging, removing subsidies leading to deforestation and degradation [71]. The facility provided funds for countries to set up structures for assessments and monitoring of carbon stocks through a readiness mechanism and then created a verifiable, tracking system for the compensation of reductions [71]. Until the growth of voluntary market REDD+ plus credits under the mechanism are largely sold to offset emission in aviation through the Carbon Offsetting and Reduction Scheme for International Aviation (CORSIA) [72, 73]. Under its current system the REDD+ experiences the challenges of double counting—which is the country of buyer and the country of the seller claiming the credits as part of their nationally determined contributions [14]. Additionally, double selling which are selling the offsets of the same land area to multiple buyers [14, 74, 75, 76].

On the whole the compliance market has drawn strong criticism in several ways. Under the CDM a disproportionately high number of projects are implemented in emerging economies with limited attention to low-income countries [77, 78, 79, 80, 81]. With the sole emphasis on forest management, the REDD+ mechanism does not create substantial results for SIDS with limited forested land. This droves the growth of the voluntary carbon market (VCM). As the programs normally referred to as standards under the VCM developed they utilized methodologies developed under the CDM and REDD+ and created premium prices on projects that supported sustainable development goals [81, 82, 83, 84].

Advertisement

4. Voluntary carbon market

The voluntary carbon market is structured in a similar way to both the CDM and the REDD+ and differs in that it allows for companies seeking to voluntarily offset their emissions to invest in projects that are reducing emissions at varying scales [85, 86]. VCM was developed in tandem with CDM and REDD+ to provide alternatives to the slow and inconsistent regulatory action [86]. It also sought to address the concerns of developing countries that offsets were utilized to outsource reduction commitments and exploit low-cost mitigation projects and provide limited benefit to communities reliant on forest resources [76, 87, 88]. As a result, VCM standards define requirements to measure reductions, accounting and sustainability. Under the VCM carbon credits can direct private financing to sustainable development activities at the local level [88, 89, 90, 91, 92] and require projects to have additional benefits such as job creation, biodiversity protection, public health improvements and scaled up these projects could supply much needed financing to the forest dependent communities of the Global South [92].

The process to develop a project under the VCM differs by the standard utilized but follows the similar process to CDM including developing a proposal, accommodating for a period of public comment, having the proposal audited for accuracy of methodology and technical soundness, approval of the project, preparation of a monitoring report to ensure that the project activities are contributing to a reduction on emissions, having the findings of monitoring report audited, approval and determination of the credits. While the structure of the VCM is similar there is more flexibility in the lengths of the monitoring periods and the frequency of issuing credits over a period of time determined by an individual project or program. As an example, a project under the VCM can have multiple monitoring periods within the 7-year time frame stipulated by the CDM, leading to a higher frequency of trades and corresponding payments. Each monitoring period does require the completion of a monitoring report that is audited and approved before the credits can be traded.

After an initial growth the voluntary carbon market was subject to slow market volumes and market value. Even after the adoption of the Paris Agreement the growth was stymied due to the uncertainty of legitimacy of voluntarily offsetting [93, 94, 95]. This lack of growth was due to the demand in the initial stages driven by public institutions while the recent demand is being driven by private institutions [96, 97]. An increased number of private companies have committed to reducing emissions through innovation and investments in the VCM. This drastic increase in interest now drives the demand for the VCM and projects that are developed with sustainable development activities receive a premium due to the emphasis on providing financing directly to forest dependent communities [93, 98]. Companies engaged in the carbon markets cover a wide range of sectors for some phasing out carbon emissions are quickly attainable particularly through utilizing renewable energy sources for electricity and transportation [93, 99]. In this case utilizing offsets are a part of the overall emissions reduction strategies. The VCM also includes companies whose business models feature very high emissions and their path towards full decarbonization is not commercially available or feasible. For companies VCM is the only viable option to achieve carbon neutrality. In a survey conducted with oil and gas companies it was determined that as companies fall short of adjusting their business-as-usual practices of exploration, offsetting would be the only option for them to meet their commitments and will continue to drive the demand for credits on the voluntary carbon market [100, 101].

The major challenge for the VCM is the occurrence of double claiming and double counting particularly in areas where payments are already being received under a compliance market mechanism [102, 103]. Double claiming and double counting will continue to be a challenge as registries under the compliance and voluntary market remain segregated. Article 6 of the Paris Agreement addresses this through corresponding adjustments ensuring that once a mitigation outcome is counted towards one party’s mitigation pledge it must be ‘un-counted’ from the other country’s pledge. While guidelines are available to avoid double counting, penalties are not forthcoming [93]. The Taskforce for Scaling the Voluntary Carbon Markets (TSVCM) published report based on consultations which noted that while private and national emissions accounting can exist separately, there may be opportunities for climate neutrality claims under the VCM to ‘be made on the back of mitigation outcomes’ outlined in the NDCs [104]. The document also notes that double counting at the national level must be avoided. Notwithstanding the strong rhetoric against double counting developing countries continue to face the multi-faceted issues associated with climate change and with limited financial resources to fund mitigation and adaptation measures the potential for funding for project to the most vulnerable and the frequency of payments continue to support a growing interest in the market.

Another key challenge of the VCM is the viability of proposed sustainable development benefits that can also reduce emissions. As case study [105] on the use of cookstoves in rural Kenya illustrates this point. Cookstoves are seen to contribute to improved air quality, fuel reduction, forest conservation and reduction of emissions but there are several issues that can affect the effectiveness of cookstoves including poor design, defects in construction maintenance and the limited firewood requirements [105]. Due to the traditional food preferences and labor requirements for construction and maintenance cookstove use is typically lower than proposed under the project [105]. However, the structure of projects emphasize incentivizes to adopt best practices in place of traditional preferences and tend to alienate beneficiaries leading inconsistent cookstove adoption by forest dependent communities from general abandonment, infrequent and unpredictable use [105]. There are also concerns over commodification of these sustainable benefits especially the ‘property’ rights over the emission reductions [105]. While these rights are key commodities in the projects there are instances when the rights associated with the activity are not directly owned by the forest dependent communities preventing them from directly benefiting from adoption of new practices [105]. It was discovered that women were required to pay a portion of the initial costs for the cookstoves whether directly out of pocket or a group lending schemes, repayment occurred over a period of time resulting in the women ‘paying’ for a cookstove that was not being utilized [105]. Additionally, the rights to the carbon offsets did not belong directly to the women and even as some of the cookstove remain idle the carbon traders continue to reap the benefits of carbon rights for an entire community [105]. As pointed out earlier in the chapter, the key challenge of carbon offsets is the emphasis on an adjustment of the behavior of the most marginalized communities in the developing countries in an effort to offset the continued practices of pollution in the developed countries [105].

The effectiveness of sustainable development projects to alter the behavior of communities reliant on forest resources contributes to the concerns on the integrity of the VCM [105] and the multifaceted nature of credits that provide sustainable development credits leads to errors and fraud [92]. High quality carbon credits—projects with sustainable development benefits are seldom well defined leading to discrepancies in accounting and verification [92]. While the market demand increases exponentially the extended time frame between the development of the project proposal and the completed sale of credits detracts buyers from making investments [92]. The varying potential of carbon offsets in the projects drive the market and projects with lower carbon potential are often overlooked based on profitability [92]. While sustainable development benefits and climate neutrality are the ultimate rewards of the projects in the VCM, their development and implementation are driven by market conditions and therefore contingent on profitability [92].

Proponents of reform in the VCM have supported the use of digital tools to provide the much-needed transparency [92]. These digital tools can be utilized for registries providing detailed information on when credits are verified and issued. More importantly they can be utilized to track the impact of projects at regular intervals and not just the end of monitoring periods when payments for credits are issued [92]. This will allow for the traceability of credits and provide greater accuracy in the offset claims used by buyers. Digital tools can also increase the involvement of individuals in the goal towards climate neutrality providing opportunities for customers to better understand the carbon footprint and provide them with opportunities to offset their emissions by contributing to projects [92].

With a growing global climate consciousness many customers are concerned with environmental issues and have expressed willingness to pay for low-carbon products which are seen as having a lower environmental impact [106, 107, 108, 109]. This incentivizes companies to provide low-carbon products and services and offset their practices that are not aligned with low carbon strategies [109, 110, 111, 112, 113]. Companies are moving towards providing information on the carbon footprint of the products and services as well providing information on the potential carbon footprint of customers utilizing the services [114]. Engaging directly with customers in the carbon markets is growing but managing the scale of investments from individuals versus the scale of investments continues to be a challenge [115]. As outlined in a study conducted by [116] utilizing blockchain technology can support data sharing which supports more efficient carbon trading and transparency in the carbon prices.

Advertisement

5. Conclusion

Carbon offsets provide very distinct opportunities for land management however how a country determines and assign carbon rights to their forest resources will impact the extent that payment in carbon offsets benefit the most marginalized communities [14, 93]. The success of the improved land management and the viability of the carbon offsets for forested areas contingent on the adoption of new practices by these communities. Countries however tend to retain latitude to assign rights to communities as the forest resources are the de facto property of the state [14, 93]. While countries enact certain legislation to afford communities reliant on forest resources land rights over forests most of fall short of explicitly assigning rights to payments from carbon offsets to these communities [14, 93]. As national governments seek to benefit from carbon rights, they are met with legal challenges due to the commodification of environmental services on a given land and the true ‘ownership’ of those services [14, 93]. While private land ownership as an indication of ownership of carbon rights is more acceptable in certain countries, the determination of rights for forest dependent communities are in flux as they are seen as stewards of the forest resources and not official owners. Countries are now faced with the challenge of differentiating between rights of communities reliant on forest resources to own land therefore benefit from the sale of offsets [14, 93].

Some countries have struck a balance by allowing communities and landowners to benefit from carbon rights subject to taxes or allowing for landowners to claim benefits that are then counted towards the country’s contribution to their NDCs [14, 93]. The corresponding adjustments are made to avoid double counting and provide progress for the country meeting their global commitments. Ultimately until there are national laws that connect compliance market or domestic schemes and the voluntary carbon markets, the credits issued under private standards remain independent from result-based payments [14, 93]. The communities’ dependency on forest resources requires keen attention to better improve the socio-economic conditions and equitable land management [117, 118]. While the importance of receiving payments for the improvement of land management is a tool to achieving global climate neutrality goals without due attention to the needs of the communities the incentives for these key actors remain woefully insufficient.

Advertisement

Conflict of interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. 1. Farooqi T, Li X, Yu Z, Liu S, Sun O. Reconcilation of research on forest carbon sequestration and water conservation. Journal of Forestry Research. 2021;32(1):7-14. DOI: 10.1007/s11676-020-01138-2
  2. 2. Zhou XL, Lei XD, Liu CX, Huang HB, Zhou C, Peng CH. Reestimating the changes and ranges of forest biomass carbon in China during the past 40 years. Forest Ecosystems. 2019;6:51
  3. 3. Sun WL, Liu XH. Review on carbon storage estimation of forest ecosystem and applications in China. Forest Ecosystems. 2020;7:4
  4. 4. Tang X, Zhao X, Bai Y, Tang Z, Wang W, Zhao Y, et al. Carbon pools in China’s terrestrial ecosystems: New estimates based on an intensive field survey. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences. 2018;115:4021-4026
  5. 5. Vashum KT, Jayakumar S. Methods to estimate above-ground biomass and carbon stock in natural forests-a review. Journal of Ecosystem and Ecography. 2012;2:1-7
  6. 6. Law BE, Turner D, Campbell J, Sun OJ, Lefsky M, Guzy M, et al. Disturbance and climate effects on carbon stocks and fluxes across the forested region of Oregon USA. Global Change Biology. 2004;10:1429-1444
  7. 7. Fang J, Chen A, Peng C, Zhao S, Ci L. Changes in forest biomass carbon storage in China between 1949 and 1998. Science. 2001;292:2320-2322
  8. 8. Sapkota Y, White J. Carbon offset market methodologies applicable for coastal wetland restoration and conservation in the United States: A review. Science of the Total Environment. 2020;701:134497. DOI: 10.1016/j.scitotenv.2019.134497
  9. 9. Lane RR, Mack SK, Day JW, et al. Fate of soil organic carbon during wetland loss. Wetlands. 2016;36:1167-1181. DOI: 10.1007/s13157-016-0834-8
  10. 10. Murray BC, Pendleton L, Jenkins WA, Sifleet S. Green Payments for Blue Carbon: Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats. Durham, NC: Nicholas Institute for Environmental Policy Solutions, Duke University; 2011. p. 52
  11. 11. Hamrick K, Gallant M. Voluntary Carbon Markets Insights: 2018 Outlook and First-Quarter Trends. Washington, DC: Forest Trends’ Ecosystem Marketplace; 2018
  12. 12. Mack SK, Lane RR, Day JW, Kempka R, Mack J, Hardee E, et al. Carbon market opportunities of Louisiana’s coastal wetlands. In: Report by Tierra Resources LLC and the Climate Trust. 2015. Available from: http://tierraresourcesllc.com/coastal-protection-projects/louisianablue-carbon-study/ [Accessed: July 3, 2023]
  13. 13. Ecosystem Marketplace. Market Watch: Compliance Market. Washington, DC: Ecosystem Marketplace, Forest Trends; 2019. Available from: http://www.ecosystemmarketplace.com/marketwatch/carbon/north-america/#compliance-markets [Accessed: July 3, 2023]
  14. 14. Streck C. Who owns REDD+? Carbon markets, carbon rights and entitlements to REDD+ finance. Forests. 2020;11:959. DOI: 10.3390/f11090959
  15. 15. Torres G. Who owns the sky past garrison lecture reprints & addenda—Seventh annual Lloyd, K. Garrison lecture on environmental law. Pace Environmental Law Review. 2001;19:515-574
  16. 16. Blumm MC. Fallacies of free market environmentalism. The free market environmentalism: The role of the market in environmental protection northwest school of law at Lewis and Clark College-1991. Harvard Journal of Law and Public Policy. 1992;15:371-390
  17. 17. Menell PS. Institutional fantasylands: From scientific management to free market environmentalism free market environmentalism: The role of the market in environmental protection northwest School of Law at Lewis and Clark College-1991. Harvard Journal of Law and Public Policy. 1992;15:489-510
  18. 18. Newell P, Paterson M. A climate for business: Global warming, the state and capital. Review of International Political Economy. 1998;5:679-703
  19. 19. Newell P, Roberts JT. The Globalization and Environment Reader. Hoboken, NJ, USA: John Wiley & Sons; 2016
  20. 20. Ciplet D, Roberts JT. Climate change and the transition to neoliberal environmental governance. Global Environmental Change. 2017;46:148-156
  21. 21. MacKenzie D. Making things the same: Gases, emission rights and the politics of carbon markets. Accounting, Organizations and Society. 2009;34:440-455
  22. 22. Government of New Zealand. Climate Change Response (Emissions Trading) Amendment Act 2008. New Zealand Legislation: Wellington, New Zealand; 2008
  23. 23. Leining C, Kerr S, Bruce-Brand B. The New Zealand emissions trading scheme: Critical review and future outlook for three design innovations. Climate Policy. 2020;20:246-264
  24. 24. Government of New Zealand. Deforesting Forest Land, Te Uru Rakau, Forestry New Zealand. Available from: https://www.mpi.govt.nz/growing-and-harvesting/forestry/forestry-in-the-emissionstrading-scheme/deforesting-forest-land/ [Accessed: July 3, 2023]
  25. 25. Savaresi A, Perugini L. The land sector in the 2030 EU climate change policy framework: A look at the future. Journal for European Environmental and Planning Law. 2019;16:148-164
  26. 26. European Commission. Commission Staff Working Document, Impact Assessment on the Role of Land Use, Land Use Change and Forestry (LULUCF) in the EU’s Climate Change Commitments. Brussels, Belgium: European Commission; 2012
  27. 27. Smith J. Afforestation and reforestation in the clean development mechanism of the Kyoto protocol: Implications for forests and forest people. International Journal of Global Environmental Issues. 2002;2(3/4):322-343
  28. 28. UNFCCC (United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change). The Marrakesh Accords & The Marrakesh Declaration. 2001. Available from: http://www.unfccc.int./
  29. 29. IISD. Summary of the sixth conference of the parties to the framework convention on climate change. Earth Negotiations Bulletin. 2000;12(163):11
  30. 30. IPCC. Land Use, Land-use Change and Forestry. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2000
  31. 31. Lessmann M, Ros G, Young M, Vries W. Global variation in soil carbon sequestration potential through improved cropland management. Global Change Biology. 2021;28(3):1162-1177
  32. 32. Bünemann EK, Bongiorno G, Bai Z, Creamer RE, De Deyn G, de Goede R, et al. Soil quality – A critical review. Soil Biology and Biochemistry. 2018;120:105-125. DOI: 10.1016/j.soilbio.2018.01.030
  33. 33. Bolinder MA, Crotty F, Elsen A, Frac M, Kismányoky T, Lipiec J, et al. The effect of crop residues, cover crops, manures and nitrogen fertilization on soil organic carbon changes in agroecosystems: A synthesis of reviews. Mitigation and Adaptation Strategies for Global Change. 2020;25(6):929-952. DOI: 10.1007/s11027-020-09916-3
  34. 34. Singh BP, Setia R, Wiesmeier M, Kunhikrishnan A. Agricultural management practices and soil organic carbon storage. In: Singh B, editor. Soil Carbon Storage: Modulators, Mechanisms and Modeling. London: Academic Press-Elsevier; 2018. pp. 1-28. DOI: 10.1016/B978-0-12-812766-7.00007-X
  35. 35. Spiegel H, Schlatter N, Haslmayr H-P, Lehtinen T, Baumgarten A. Compatibility of agricultural management practices and types of farming in the EU to enhance climate change mitigation and soil health policy bundles framing agricultural soil protection in EU and selected member states. Netherlands: Wageningen Research, Wageningen University; 2014. Available from: https://research.wur.nl/en/projects/compatibility-of-agricultural-management-practices-and-types-of-f-2
  36. 36. Van Groenigen KJ, Qi X, Osenberg CW, Luo Y, Hungate BA. Faster decomposition under increased atmospheric CO2 limits soil carbon storage. Science (New York, N.Y.). 2014;344(6183):508-509. DOI: 10.1126/science.1249534
  37. 37. De Vries W. Soil carbon 4 per mille: A good initiative but let's manage not only the soil but also the expectations. Geoderma. 2018;292:111-112. DOI: 10.1016/j.geoderma.2017.05.023
  38. 38. Beillouin D et al. A Global Overview of Studies about the Land Management, Land-use Change, and Climate Change Effects on Soil Carbon. New Jersey, United States: Wiley; 2021. DOI: 10.1111/gcb.15998
  39. 39. Batjes NH. Total carbon and nitrogen in the soils of the world. European Journal of Soil Science. 1996;47(2):151-163. DOI: 10.1111/j.1365-2389.1996.tb01386.x
  40. 40. Goldstein A, Turner WR, Spawn SA, Anderson-Teixeira KJ, CookPatton S, Fargione J, et al. Protecting irrecoverable carbon in Earth's ecosystems. Nature Climate Change. 2020;10(4):287-295. DOI: 10.1038/s41558-020-0738-8
  41. 41. Don A, Schumacher J, Freibauer A. Impact of tropical land-use change on soil organic carbon stocks—A metaanalysis. Global Change Biology. 2011;17(4):1658-1670. DOI: 10.1111/j.1365-2486.2010.02336
  42. 42. Friedlingstein P, O'Sullivan M, Jones MW, Andrew RM, Hauck J, Olsen A, et al. Global carbon budget 2020. Earth System Science Data. 2020;12(4):3269-3340. DOI: 10.5194/essd-12-3269-2020
  43. 43. Crowther TW, Todd-Brown KEO, Rowe CW, Wieder WR, Carey JC, MacHmuller MB, et al. Quantifying global soil carbon losses in response to warming. Nature. 2016;540:104-108. DOI: 10.1038/nature20150
  44. 44. Paul EA. The nature and dynamics of soil organic matter: Plant inputs, microbial transformations, and organic matter stabilization. Soil Biology and Biochemistry. 2016;98:109-126. DOI: 10.1016/j.soilbio.2016.04.001
  45. 45. Dignac M-F, Derrien D, Barré P, Barot S, Cécillon L, Chenu C, et al. Increasing soil carbon storage: Mechanisms, effects of agricultural practices and proxies. A review. Agronomy for Sustainable Development. 2017;37(2):14. DOI: 10.1007/s13593-017-0421-2
  46. 46. Fujisaki K, Chevallier T, Chapuis-Lardy L, Albrecht A, Razafimbelo T, Masse D, et al. Soil carbon stock changes in tropical croplands are mainly driven by carbon inputs: A synthesis. Agriculture, Ecosystems & Environment. 2018;259:147-158. DOI: 10.1016/j.agee.2017.12.008
  47. 47. Wiesmeier M, Urbanski L, Hobley E, Lang B, von Lützow M, MarinSpiotta E, et al. Soil organic carbon storage as a key function of soils—A review of drivers and indicators at various scales. Geoderma. 2019;333:149-162. DOI: 10.1016/j.geoderma.2018.07.026
  48. 48. Lehmann J et al. Biochar in climate change mitigation. Nature Geoscience. 2021;14:883-892. DOI: 10.1038/s41561-021-00852-8
  49. 49. Hansen et al. Agriculural residues bioenergy potential that sustain soil carbon depends on energy conversion pathways. CCB-Bioenergy. 2020;12(11):1002-1013. DOI: 10.1111/gcbb.12733
  50. 50. Scarlat N, Martinov M, Dallemand JF. Assessment of the availability of agricultural crop residues in the European Union: Potential and limitations for bioenergy use. Waste Management. 2010;30(10):1889-1897. DOI: 10.1016/j.wasman.2010.04.016
  51. 51. United States Department of Agriculture-Natural Resource Conservation Service (USDA-NRCS), 2006. White Paper Crop Residue Removal for Biomass Energy Production: Effects on Soils and Recommendations. Available from: http://soils.usda.gov/sqi/management/files/AgForum_Residue_White_Paper.pdf
  52. 52. Zomer R. Climate change mitigation: A spatial analysis of global land suitability for clean development mechanism afforestation and reforestation. Agriculture, Ecosystems and Environment. 2008;126:67-80. DOI: 10.1016/j.agee.2008.01.014
  53. 53. Cosbey A, Parry JE, Browne J, Babu YD, Bandachari P, Drexhage J, et al. Realizing the Development Dividend: Making the CDM Work for Developing Countries. Moanitoba, Canada: International Institute for Sustainable Development; 2005. 72 p
  54. 54. Smith J, Scherr S. Forests, Carbon and Local Livelihoods: An Assessment of Opportunities and Policy Recommendations. Bogor, Indonesia: CIFOR; 2002
  55. 55. Gillenwater M, Seres S. The clean development mechanism: A review of the first international offset programme. Greenhouse Gas Measurement and Management. 2011;1(3-4):179-203
  56. 56. Hultman N. A review of community co-benefits of the clean development mechanism. Environmental Research Letters. 2020;15:053002. DOI: 10.1088/1748-9326/ab6396
  57. 57. Dirix J, Peeters W, Sterckx S. Is the clean development mechanism delivering benefits to the poorest communities in the developing world? A critical evaluation and proposals for reform. Environment, Development and Sustainability. 2016;18:839-855
  58. 58. Petticrew M, Roberts H. Systematic Reviews in the Social Sciences: A Practical Guide. New York: Wiley; 2008
  59. 59. Pearson B. Market failure: Why the clean development mechanism will not promote clean development. Journal of Cleaner Production. 2007;15:247-252
  60. 60. Phelps J, Webb E, Agrawal A. Does REDD+ threaten to recentralize forest governance. Science. 2010;328(5976):312-313. DOI: 10.1126/science.1187774
  61. 61. Miles L, Kapos V. Reducing greenhouse gas emissions from deforestation and forest degradation: Global land-use implications. Science. 2008;320:1454-1455. DOI: 10.1126/science.1155358
  62. 62. Angelsen A, Wertz-Kanounnikoff S. In: Angelsen A, editor. Moving Ahead with REDD: Issues, Options and Implications. Bogor, Indonesia: Center for International Forestry Research; 2008. pp. 11-22
  63. 63. Minang PA, Murphy D. REDD after Copenhagen: The Way Forward. Nairobi: World Agroforestry Center; 2010. Available from: www.asb.cgiar.org/PDFwebdocs/REDD_After_Copenhagen-EN.pdf
  64. 64. United Nations. Framework Convention on Climate Change. 1771 UNTS 107: New York, NY, USA: United Nations Treaty Collection; 1994
  65. 65. UNFCCC. Warsaw Framework for REDD-Plus. Bonn, Germany: UNFCCC; 2013; Decisions 9-15/CP19
  66. 66. UNFCCC. Warsaw Framework for REDD-Plus, Modalities for Measuring, Reporting and Verifying. Bonn, Germany: UNFCCC; 2013; Decision 14/CP.19; Para. 15
  67. 67. NYDF Assessment Partners. Goal 9: Reward Positive Results/New York Declaration on Forests; Goal Assessment Update. Washington, DC, USA: NYDF Assessment Partners; 2019. p. 9
  68. 68. International Bank on Reconstruction and Development. General Conditions Applicable to Emission Reductions Payment Agreements; The Forest Carbon Partnership Facility. Washington, DC, USA: World Bank; 2014. Available from: https://www.forestcarbonpartnership.org/erpa-general-conditions [Accessed: July 1, 2023]
  69. 69. United Nations. The Kyoto Protocol to the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change. New York, NY, USA: United Nations Treaty Collection, C.N.101.2004; 1997
  70. 70. Johns T et al. A three-fund approach to incorporating government, public and private forest stewards into a REDD funding mechanism. International Forestry Review. 2008;10(3):458-464
  71. 71. Karsenty A. The architecture of proposed REDD schemes after Bali facing critical choices. International Forestry Review. 2008;10(3):443-457
  72. 72. Verified Carbon Standard. Data Insights. 2020. Available from: https://verra.org/datainsights/april-2020/ [Accessed: July 1, 2023]
  73. 73. Chagas T, Galt H, Lee D, Neeff T, Streck C. Should Forest Carbon Credits Be Included in Offsetting Schemes Such as CORSIA? Washington, DC, USA: Climate Focus; 2019
  74. 74. Andonova L, Sun Y. Private governance in developing countries: Drivers of voluntary carbon offset programs. Global Environmental Politics. 2019;19:1. DOI: 10.1162/glep_a_00496
  75. 75. Green J. Rethinking Private Authority Agents and Entrepreneurs in Global Environmental Governance. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press; 2014
  76. 76. Paterson M, Hoffmann M, Betsill M, Bernstein S. The micro foundations of policy diffusion toward complex global governance: An analysis of the transnational carbon emission trading network. Comparative Political Studies. 2014;47(3):420-449
  77. 77. Biedenkopf K, Müller P, Slominski P, Wettestad J. A global turn to greenhouse gas emissions trading? Experiments, actors, and diffusion. Global Environmental Politics. 2017;17(3):1-11
  78. 78. Hale T, Roger C. Domestic politics and Chinese participation in transnational climate governance. In: Kennedy S, editor. China and Global Governance: The Dragon’s Learning Curve. London, England: Routledge; 2017
  79. 79. Schröder M. Local Climate Governance in China: Hybrid Actors and Market Mechanisms. New York, NY: Palgrave Macmillan; 2012
  80. 80. Castro P, Michaelowa A. Would preferential access measures be sufficient to overcome current barriers to CDM projects in least developed countries? Climate and Development. 2011;3(2):123-142
  81. 81. Andonova LB. Public–private partnerships for the Earth: Politics and patterns of hybrid authority in the multilateral system. Global Environmental Politics. 2010;10(2):25-53
  82. 82. Michaelowa A, Michaelowa K. Climate business for poverty reduction? The role of the World Bank. Review of International Organizations. 2011;6(3-4):259-286
  83. 83. Green J. Order out of chaos: Public and private rules for managing carbon. Global Environmental Politics. 2013;13(2):1-25
  84. 84. Lovell HC. Governing the carbon offset market. Wiley Interdisciplinary Reviews: Climate Change. 2010;1(3):353-362
  85. 85. Bumpus AG, Liverman DM. Accumulation by decarbonization and the governance of carbon offsets. Economic Geography. 2008;84(2):127-155
  86. 86. Abbott KW, Green JF, Keohane RO. Organizational ecology and institutional change in global governance. International Organization. 2016;70(2):247-277
  87. 87. Hamilton K, Sjardin M, Shapiro A, Marcello T. Fortifying the Foundation: State of the Voluntary Carbon Markets 2009. New York, NY: New Carbon Finance; 2009
  88. 88. Bernstein S. Liberal environmentalism and global environmental governance. Global Environmental Politics. 2002;2(3):1-16
  89. 89. Newell P, Paterson M. Climate Capitalism: Global Warming and the Transformation of the Global Economy. Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press; 2010
  90. 90. Roberts JT, Parks B. A Climate of Injustice: Global Inequality, North-South Politics, and Climate Policy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press; 2006
  91. 91. Wara M, Victor D. A Realistic Policy on International Carbon Offsets. PESD Working Paper 74. CA: Stanford University; 2008
  92. 92. Blaufelder C; Levy C; Mannion P.; Pinner D.A blueprint for scaling voluntary carbon markets to meet the climate challenge. Available from: https://www.mckinsey.com/capabilities/sustainability/our-insights/a-blueprint-for-scaling-voluntary-carbon-markets-to-meet-the-climate-challenge
  93. 93. Kreibich N, Hermwille L. Caught in between: Credibility and feasibility of the voluntary carbon market post-2020. Climate Policy. 2021;21(7):939-957. DOI: 10.1080/14693062.2021.1948384
  94. 94. Donofrio S, Maguire P, Zwick S, Merry W. Voluntary carbon and the post-pandemic recovery. In: Forest Trends. Available from: https://www.ecosystemmarketplace.com/carbon-markets/. 2020 [Accessed: July 1, 2023]
  95. 95. Hermwille L. Climate change as a transformation challenge – A new climate policy paradigm? GAIA – Ecological Perspectives for Science and Society. 2016;25(1):19-22. DOI: 10.14512/gaia.25.1.6
  96. 96. Donofrio S, Maguire P, Zwick S, Merry W. The only constant is change – State of the voluntary carbon markets 2020, second installment. Forest Trends. 2020:23. Available from: https://share.hsforms.com/1FhYs1TapTE-qBxAxgy-jgg1yp8f [Accessed: July 1, 2023]
  97. 97. Rogelj J, Geden O, Cowie A, Reisinger A. Net-zero emissions targets are vague: Three ways to fix. Nature. 2021;591(7850):365-368. DOI: 10.1038/d41586-021-00662-3
  98. 98. UNEP Finance Initiative. The Portfolio Decarbonization Coalition. 2020. Available from: https://unepfi.org/pdc/ [Accessed: July 3, 2023]
  99. 99. Machnik D, Sun P, Tänzler D. Climate neutrality targets of European companies and the role of carbon offsetting. Adelphi. 2020:60
  100. 100. Tong D, Trout K. Big oil reality check – Assessing oil and gas company climate plans. Oil Change International. Available from: http://priceofoil.org/content/uploads/2020/09/OCI-Big-Oil-Reality-Check-vF.pdf. 2020 [Accessed: July 3, 2023]
  101. 101. Kachi A, Mooldijk S, Warnecke C. Climate Neutrality Claims. Cologne, Germany: NewClimate Institute; 2020. p. 23. Available from: https://newclimate.org/wp-content/uploads/2020/09/Climate_neutrality_claims_BUND_September2020.pdf [Accessed: July 3, 2023]
  102. 102. Gold Standard. A New Paradigm for Voluntary Climate Action: ‘Reduce Within, Finance Beyond’. 2017. Available from: https://www.goldstandard.org/sites/default/files/documents/a_new_paradigm_for_voluntary_climate_action.pdf [Accessed: July 3, 2023]
  103. 103. Hamrick K, Gallant M. Unlocking Potential – State of the Voluntary Carbon Markets 2017. 2017. Available from: http://www.forest-trends.org/documents/files/doc_5591.pdf
  104. 104. TSVCM. Consultation Document. Taskforce on Scaling Voluntary Carbon Markets. 2020. Available from: https://www.iif.com/Portals/1/Files/TSVCM_Consultation_Document.pdf [Accessed: July 1, 2023]
  105. 105. Wang Y, Corson C. The making of a ‘charismatic’ carbon credit: Clean cookstoves and ‘uncooperative’ women in Western Kenya. Environment and Planning A: Economy and Space. 2015;47(10):2064-2079
  106. 106. Tong W et al. The impact of cap-and-trade mechanism and consumers’ environmental preferences on a retailer-led supply chain. Resources, Conservation & Recycling. 2019;142:88-100. DOI: 10.1016/j.resconrec.2018.11.005
  107. 107. Manohar HL, Kumar RG. Impact of green supply chain management attributes on sustainable supply chains. International Journal of Supply Chain and Operations Resilience. 2016;2:291-314. DOI: 10.1504/IJSCOR.2016.084030
  108. 108. Xu L, Wang C. Sustainable manufacturing in a closed-loop supply chain considering emission reduction and remanufacturing. Resources, Conservation and Recycling. 2017;131:297-304. DOI: 10.1016/j.resconrec.2017.10.012
  109. 109. Du S, Zhu J, Jiao H, Ye W. Game-theoretical analysis for supply chain with consumer preference to low carbon. International Journal of Production Research. 2015;53:3753-3768. DOI: 10.1080/00207543.2014.988888
  110. 110. Janssen M, Jager W. Stimulating diffusion of green products. Journal of Evolutionary Economics. 2002;12:283-306. DOI: 10.1007/s00191-002-0120-1
  111. 111. Swami S, Shah J. Channel coordination in green supply chain management. The Journal of the Operational Research Society. 2013;64:336-351. DOI: 10.1057/jors.2012.44
  112. 112. Pu X, Shi Q , Ling L. Effect of direct marking on retailing channels where large retailers exist. Journal of Management Sciences in China. 2007;10:49-56. DOI: 10.3321/j.issn:1007-9807.2007.06.006
  113. 113. Lai K, Tang AKY. Green retailing: Factors for success. California Management Review. 2010;52:6-31. DOI: 10.1525/cmr.2010.52.2.6
  114. 114. Styles D, Schoenberger H, Galvez-Martos JL. Environmental improvement of product supply chains: A review of European retailers’ performance. Resources, Conservation & Recycling. 2012;65:57-78. DOI: 10.1016/j.resconrec.2012.05.002
  115. 115. Tuten T. Promoting sustainability by marketing green products to non-adopters. Gest. 2013;2000(30):93. DOI: 10.3917/g2000.302.0093
  116. 116. He H, Luo Z, Wang Q, Chen M, He H, Gao L, et al. Joint operation mechanism of distributed photovoltaic power generation market and carbon market based on cross-chain trading technology. IEEE Access. 2020;8:66116-66130. DOI: 10.1109/ACCESS.2020.2985577
  117. 117. Johnson CAB. Evaluation of Spatial Fragmentation of Protected Areas Using the Spatial Assessment for Coastal Protected Areas in Caribbean Small Island Developing States. ProQuest Dissertations & Theses. 2020
  118. 118. Moreaux C, Zafra-Calvo N, Vansteelant NG, Wicander S, Burgess ND. Can existing assessment tools be used to track equity in protected area management under Aichi Target 11? Biological Conservation. 2018;224:242-247

Written By

Carianne Johnson

Submitted: 02 August 2023 Reviewed: 09 August 2023 Published: 13 November 2023