Open access peer-reviewed chapter

The Financing of Spanish Colonial Commerce in America: The Almojarifazgo and the Port of Veracruz

Written By

Emiliano Gil-Blanco

Submitted: 27 July 2019 Reviewed: 24 September 2019 Published: 12 March 2020

DOI: 10.5772/intechopen.89885

From the Edited Volume

Perspectives on Economic Development - Public Policy, Culture, and Economic Development

Edited by Ryan Merlin Yonk and Vito Bobek

Chapter metrics overview

606 Chapter Downloads

View Full Metrics

Abstract

The Hacienda Real during the colony taxed the commerce with several tariffs, the most important being the avería and the almojarifazgo. The latter would do so directly on traded goods. The information it gives is a rich source for interpreting colonial and intercontinental trade. The study focuses on the documentation of tax by the Real Caja de Veracruz at the New-Hispanic port of Veracruz, which served as the re-shipper of the goods negotiated in Mexico. It gives us information about incoming and outgoing ships, their destinations or origins, and the amount paid for almojarifazgo, without distinctions. The total value negotiated in the port between 1587 and 1650 has been calculated as a percentage charged on the value of the merchandise. In spite of fraud and contraband during this whole period, these calculations can be considered a source of reliable, if approximate, information of the new Spanish trade. It establishes the supremacy of imports over exports and intercontinental trade with Spain over colonial trade.

Keywords

  • Almojarifazgo
  • tax law
  • trade commerce
  • Veracruz
  • New Spain

La serie de almojarifazgo percibido en Veracruz sobre los movimientos de los navíos con España y América permanece casi constante. Nada hace pensar en una modificación radical de la eficacia de las obligaciones fiscales.

(Chaunu [1], p. 542)

Advertisement

1. Introduction

The maintenance of the Spanish trading system with America in large part was based on the collection of a series of taxes levied on the value of goods traded there, such as the breakdown, the duty of tonnes, the Admiralty, the market or the almojarifazgo. Each of them took on a specific function within the system. The breakdown was the source of funding for the navies protecting the Convoys of the Race of the Indies. The right of tons financed the expenses of the University of Mareantes de Sevilla, while the Admiralty did the same with the salary of the admirals of Castile and the lonja with the Consulate.

Of all these taxes, the almojarifazgo, or income of the sea, was the only one that was not collected for a specific purpose, but rather, financed the bureaucracy and expenses of the Castilian Crown in general, both in America and in the Metropolis. Its origin dates back to the time of the Arab domination of the peninsula. With the conquest of the city of Seville in 1248 by Ferdinand III the Holy, this tax was increased by the Hacienda Real and was later regulated by Alfonso X. From the outset, the system of collection of this tax varied from port to port and was carried out through the lease of this tax by third parties.

To better understand what colonial taxation was in general we must highlight a recent work on taxation, coordinated by Pilar Martínez, Ernest Sánchez and Matilde Souto [2], in which they study the works of Bartholome Yun, on taxation within the context of the nation state [3]. More specifically, for the almojarifazgo we highlight the research essays of Emiliano Gil, who has also worked on the history of the port of Veracruz and its trade [4, 5, 6, 7], by Manuel Moreyra Paz-Soldán [8], by Manuel J. Ayala [9] or Luis Salas Almela, about the almojarifazgo in Seville and Sanlúcar de Barrameda [10, 11]. There is, as can be seen, a sparse historiography about the almojarifazgo for the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries for the New Spain viceroyalty. The same is not true of other taxes, such as Ernest Sánchez’s studies on New Spain [12], Guillermina Valle on its management and the Consulate of Mexico [13] or Yovana Celaya on tax administration in the seventeenth century [14], or the breakdown of the classic study of Guillermo Céspedes [1, 15]. On the contrary, the eighteenth century has been studied more deeply, not only in New Spain, but in other American areas that began their expansion in that century, as is the case of Río de la Plata. Most use other tax sources or vessel registrations [16].

Advertisement

2. The tax

In 1497, after the discovery of America, the Catholic Monarchs extended the collection of the almojarifazgo to the trade of goods sent to that continent, exempting from the payment of this and any other rights to intercolonial trade and to all products Americans exported from the new territories annexed to the metropolis without exception ([17], pp. 209–210; [18], p. 105).1 Initially, the collection of this tax was intended for the financing of the colonial administration, although the Crown initially imposed it to justify the high costs of its policy.

The exact date of its implementation in America is unknown to us, but the advance of the conquest and colonization of the new colonies was matched by the implementation of the Real Caja. In this way, the Caribbean islands were the first to see the Castilian fiscal power deployed, having been the first territories discovered and conquered, later to New Spain and then to Central and South America. We have news that in 1528 the almojarifazgo was already collected in the viceroyalty of New Spain and in 1543 in that of Peru [19].

From the Caja Real of February 28, 1543, ([17], pp. 210–211), the collection of this duty was extended to all products imported from Europe, with export and intercolonial trade remaining free of charge. At the same time, this Real Cédula introduced another tax in America on the value of goods, the alcabala, which taxed the first sale of items in American markets. The collection rates of the almojarifazgo were established in 2.5% of the goods declared from Seville and 5% for entry into the Americas (p. 21; [18], pp. 105–106).

As can be seen, the Caja Real of 1543 did not change the system established in 1497. The novelty was based on how to raise the almojarifazgo, a portion in the port of departure and the rest in the arrival port, when it was previously collected in its entirety in the Sevillian port. To this 7.5% of almojarifazgo we must add 10% of first sale alcabala, which in fact was taxed on goods at 17.5% of their value at destination. In cases where products imported from the metropolis were re-exported to other American ports, the Caja Real re-taxed them with another 5% [20].

This tax was applied once certain American agricultural products began to be exported, which was the beginning of a much bulkier trade to Europe. After a series of consultations with the king, held between 1559 and 1566 ([21], p. 218), and after consulting the Council of the Indies. The king decided to reorganize the collection of almojarifazgo. The Caja Real was issued on 29 May 15662 and the Real Provisión of December 28, 1568.3 The Crown sought an expansion of its revenue in American trade, as it was hardly exposed to the fiscal pressure of the time, and also because it obtained great benefits and privileges.

The Real Cédula of 1566 doubled the percentages that they charged as almojarifazgo for intercontinental trade, looking at a 5% departure from Seville, previously it was 2.5%, with 10% entry into ports enabled for trade with America. In addition, Andalusian wines, which constituted one of the most exported products to the American colonies, were also traded with an additional 10% in both Seville and America.4

The Real Provisión of 1568 imposed the almojarifazgo for the first time on intercolonial trade, which in New Spain began to be applied within the general reform of Viceroy Martín Enríquez ([22], pp. 217–228) and in Peru by the Bachelor Lope García de Castro (1564–1569) under the viceroy Francisco de Toledo. The instructions for developing the new contributory system, as established by Moreyra ([8], p. 17) and Borah ([21], p. 218), did not reach the major ports until 1571.

According to this Provisión, goods exported to other colonial ports were required to pay the Caja Real 2.5% of the declared value, at the port of departure, as stipulated for export trade to Europe. Goods introduced or imported from colonial origin had since then paid 5% of their value at the port of destination. Whereas, European products re-exported between the same American colonies paid the Royal Treasury 5%, not on their declared value at the port of destination, but on the price difference between the latter and the port of origin manifested in the vessels’ records. In order for the collection of the almojarifazgo to be carried out faithfully, the Crown necessarily extended the elaboration of records for intercolonial traffic.5 With this Real Provisión, the circuit was closed for collecting the rights of almojarifazgo of Indian trade until the end of the eighteenth century.

The imposition of these new tariffs was by no means accepted by those most directly affected by merchants. In New Spain the merchants maintained a relationship with Viceroy Enríquez, who in turn sent them to Castile, in which they explained the possible consequences of the new collection on trade due to such a substantial increase in taxes ([22], pp. 221–222). In the Peruvian viceroyalty the opposition of traders and the Real Audiencia to the new almojarifazgo was such that its application had to be delayed until 1566 reducing it to 1% instead of the stipulated 5% ([8], p. 17). Also, as a result of these protests, the tariff on Sevillian wines was reduced to 7.5% ([17], p. 212).6

In fact, the economic repercussions of the increase in almojarifazgo in American trade were very different from the alarmist relations of traders on both continents.

Advertisement

3. Exemptions and reductions in the collection of almojarifazgo

Despite the mandatory charge of tax on all products, there were always exemptions at certain ports for political or economic reasons. Of course, there was no almojarifazgo on any of those products for the service of the Crown, both in America and in the Iberian Peninsula, as well as ammunition, bastimentos and equipment for the boats of the Carrera de Indias ([17], pp. 215 and 218).7 Its application was initially carried out on the ships that were escorting the convoys and then extending to all those who participated in Indian Ocean traffic.

From early on, the personal belongings of travelers were exempt from tax, as long as they were not sold at the destination. The royal officers were tasked with enforcing these rules. In the case of the sale of any belonging, it was penalized with the collection of double the percentage of the respective almojarifazgo. When there were intermediaries of third parties, the goods were seized along with half of the assets of the complainant, which were distributed to third parties between the Crown, the judge and the complainant.8

Another article partially exempt from the payment of the almojarifazgo were books, continuing an ancient privilege established by the Catholic Monarchs (1480) that exempted from tax on all books introduced in Castile by sea and by land ([18], p. 106; [17], p. 218).9 In America they were taxed by the avería, as was done with the importation of azogue. For the former there was a second customs office in Veracruz, that of the Inquisition, in order to filter those not in accordance with the governing doctrines of the Catholic Church of the time ([23], p. 75).

Certain ports also saw the almojarifazgo reduced in order to boost their trade. The Crown’s policy of creating a monopoly trade capitalized by a single port of exit and another of entry meant that the rest of the colonies, with exceptions, were kept away from the trade routes until the Free Trade Decree of 1778. This gap was filled by smuggling with foreigners and by a few trade contacts that the Colonies maintained with each other. To this end, the Crown would grant reductions in the tax, especially leaving port, during certain periods to boost “legal” trade. This privilege was only directed to products exported to the metropolis according to Antúnez ([17], pp. 213–214), Lorenzo ([19], pp. 371–372) and Haring ([18], p. 107), referring to the documents of February 2, 1561 and May 8, 1577.

These reductions are also found in several Venezuelan ports at the end of the sixteenth century. Specifically, tax rates for intercolonial trade were halved. Cumaná obtained this privilege in 1589, Margarita in 1592, Caracas in 1592 and 1597, Río Hacha (New Kingdom of Granada) in 1596 and Nueva Andalucía in 1597 ([19], pp. 371 and 372; [18], p. 107; [24], p. 39). Cartagena would receive permits to reduce the collection of taxes by 1535, 1539 and 1540, in this case for goods that encouraged local agriculture and livestock ([25], p. 62).10

Puerto Rico received this benefit in 1567, 1606, 1611, 1625, 1632 and 1636 ([26], pp. 224–225; [19], pp. 371–372). Specifically, the almojarifazgo was reduced in half to give incentive to the island’s trade in leather and sugar. The Cuban port of Havana was also granted this right for the years 1569, 1577, 1589 and 1595 ([19], pp. 371–372).

Advertisement

4. Evaluation of the value of goods and revenue

Royal officers calculated the tax on merchandise value from the prices at the port of origin or destination within thirty days of being shipped or landed ([17], pp. 235 and 236; [27], pp. 479–481).11 The source for his calculation was the records of the vessels or affidavit produced by the merchant. As noted by Antúnez ([17], p. 233) and Lorenzo ([19], pp. 378–379) in reference to the accounting of the Caja Real de Veracruz,12 they included, with day, month and year, the goods they transported and their value, declaring bale to bale and crate by crate. This statement was not systematically verified, nor was purchased and sale invoices required, unless there was evidence of fraud or reporting.

This non-verification of the declared was a privilege of Indian traders and shippers ([28], p. 165). Very rarely were they checked by the royal officers. To avoid this, there were the respective consulates who with their donations and petitions to the Crown managed to wipe out the most jealous official and obtain greater privileges for their trade. The delays that would result from such inquiries in the loading and unloading of fleets and vessels were in their favour, as this delay would create increments in their profits and in the collection of taxes. In order to grant these privileges, the Crown issued a certificate in 1586, urging its officials not to open the loaded bales and to speed up the dispatch of fleets and vessels ([17], 1797, pp. 237–238).

This privilege was met with the opposition of some royal officials. Thus, we can see how in 1596 the Casa de la Contratación objected to royal officials investigating the contents of bales and loaded crates. The same situation was repeated in 1604, but this controversy ended in 1609 with a certificate prohibiting the inspection of what was stated in the records ([17], p. 241). A relationship of two officers from the Real Caja de México of this time confirms this situation.

As can be gleened from the text, this privilege favoured fraud in legal trade. The amounts reported as evasion by the two New Spain officers may be exaggerated, but the reality was that the omission of goods or their undervaluation in the registers amounted to between 75 and 80% of what was traded in the fleets ([19], p. 378). One way of circumventing fiscal control was the loading and/or unloading of goods out of port or the exchange between ships on the high seas, claiming that they were registered on other vessels or could not be because of the haste of departure of the fleet or vessel.

The existence of this fraud would not be understood without the participation of the same royal officers and even the authorities, since many of them bought their positions from the Crown, particularly in the seventeenth century, and needed to make them profitable in order to compensate the expenditure made to attain them.

To curb tax evasion, the Crown drafted a number of rules. Merchants or travellers often did not declare goods they brought to America in order to pay for their journey with their sale, or to concel their existence from the Caja Real, in order to pay less almojarifazgo tax. From this moment on, they had to be declared in the corresponding register of the vessel. Thus, in 1574 all undeclared goods were obliged to pay the almojarifazco on arrival as if they had actually been registered, including those rescued from shipwrecked vessels ([17], p. 216).13

In 1624 the Consulate and the Hacienda Real changed the system of collection of the almojarifazgo, in a clear attempt to prevent fraud in the records. From this year a fixed value was imposed for each crate or bale loaded, according to weight and goods contained within. This measure contributed even more to enhancing fraud, as traders did not load declared goods, but rather goods of higher value. In addition, the need to weigh bales before being loaded on the ships lengthened the loading period and, therefore, that of their departure. This system of capacity was replaced in 1695 by that of palmeo ([17], pp. 246–247).

Initially, the payment method of the almojarifazgo was in merchandise, from the same products traded, but from 1568 it was collected in cash with no exception. In 1620, it was converted back to the more primitive form of payment, suggesting that both ways of complying with the Real Caja were used in parallel for many years ([17], pp. 214–215).14

The Crown did not allow the payment of this tax to be postponed,15 although the reality was another by allowing royal officials to trust in Seville and America. Payment was made in advance of the sale of the goods, withholding them in case of non-payment. Nevertheless, the major cash-flow problems that the established commercial system originated in traders made delay, installments and credit in paying the tax, function on a daily basis. For the Sevillian case they had to wait for the return voyage to be able to pay the almojarifazgo. At other times, traders anticipated 5% of the total goods tax, and the rest was paid on the return of the fleet or vessel. It could also happen that the payment was deferred for 4 years, paying 70% of the total the first year and the rest in the following three.

These “illegal” forms of payment of the tax were not condoned by the Crown, hence between 1550 and 1627 five Real Cédulas were issued to combat it,16 in which for the first time they sanctioned those officials who transgressed the rules with the payment of 4% penalty.

How was almojarifazgo charged in Veracruz? There were usually two officers of the Caja Real, a treasurer and an accountant, and, in very rare cases, an agent appears. Their attitude was solidary and collegiate, as can be assumed, before the Court of Auditors of Mexico. Once the boats arrived at port, the masters handed over the records to the royal officers. With the records in hand, they authorized the unloading of the merchandise, which was stored in the warehouses of the Caja Real as a guarantee of future payment of the tax. In order to have independence and be able to calculate the value and tax of the declared goods, the officers had to agree and remained isolated to evaluate them. The value of the merchandise was calculated, as we have already mentioned, according to the value it had in the port thirty days after its arrival, taking into account the average price of its wholesale value ([17], pp. 235–236; [19], p. 380).17 To carry out this calculation and check or set the prices, they had at hand the regulations of the almojarifazgo and were accompanied by three witnesses, not merchants.

Once the value of the goods had been established, it was sent to Mexico for consideration by the Caja Real de México. This was composed of the viceroy, hearers, prosecutor of the Real Audiencia and officials of the Caja de México. The calculation of what traders had to pay for almojarifazgo was then calculated. Once the tax was calculated, it was again sent to Veracruz for the royal officers of that port to effect the payment. This system was created by Viceroy Enríquez in 1573 after consultation with all those involved in the New Spain trade, including royal officers, and accepted by the Crown in 1593. For the reforms of Viceroy Martín Enríquez see García-Abasolo ([22], pp. 226–227). For the acceptance of the conditions by Enríquez, Real Cédula of January 17, 1593, go to Antúnez ([17], pp. 239–240) and Lorenzo ([19], p. 380).

But the value of the goods calculated according to existing prices in the port of Veracruz was fictitious, since very few were sold in that port. Veracruz was only a distribution point and Mexico was in charge of its sale and redistribution to the rest of the New Spain territory. That is why in 1576 Viceroy Enríquez ordered that the price of merchandise be calculated according to the highest, medium and lowest value that had occurred in its sale, taking into account that it was produced on credit ([22], pp. 227–228). When this calculation was made, they took into account shipping costs and damage to goods during transport or from storage in the port warehouses.

The fact that the real market of unloaded goods in Veracruz was the capital of the viceroyalty influenced its collection of almojarifazgo. The merchants resided in the latter city, negotiated the goods there and paid their taxes. The officers of the Veracruz caja had to record these payments as made in the same port,18 along with all the data of the vessels. For each period of accounts of each royal-service officer four relationships were established: 10% almojarifazgo for entry of vessels from Seville; 5% for the entry period from the American colonies; a 2.5% departure fee bound for the first; and a 2.5% departure tax to colonies. They included, in addition to the paid almojarifazgo, the type and name of the boat, its master, the origin and destination of the same and the date of entry or departure from the port. Sometimes they also recorded the person who paid the tax at the Caja, but this was done very rarely.

Advertisement

5. Fundraising

During the period between 1587 and 1650, notwithstanding gaps in documentation,19 a total of 5,433,564.8 pesos were collected at the Caja de Veracruz, as an almojarifazgo, of which 4,957,826.4 pesos were collected (91.2%), and the remaining 475,738.4 pesos for exports (8.8%).20 From these two quantities and their evolution we estimate that the total value of the goods of the trade of Veracruz was 72,836,207 pesos, of which 53,798,475 belong to imports and 19,037,732 pesos to exports. The port’s trade balance, as can be seen, was negative at 19,037,732 pesos. This was compensated with the export of numerary, already studied by Hamilton ([29], pp. 47–56) and Eufemio Lorenzo Sanz ([19], pp. 252–253) and which we present a comparison in Table 1.

YearsHamiltonLorenzo
1571–15755,250,848.606,961,106.70
1576–15804,452,950.007,071,426.70
1581–15857,638,402.8010,010,691.00
1586–15906,315,767.206,003,871.10
1591–15959,812,990.506,174,575.60
1596–16007,974,421.909,231,595.60
1601–16055,901,535.90
1606–16107,542,324.20
1611–16156,060,319.70
1616–16208,759,988.50
1621–16258,847,808.80
1626–16304,270,502.30
1631–16352,722,946.40
1636–16404,649,319.60
1641–16452,188,833.70
1646–16502,223,195.50
Total94,612,155.6045,453,266.70

Table 1.

New Spain exportations of silver from private owners, merchants and assets of deceased persons.

Source Hamilton and Lorenzo Sanz.

Export superiority over import was substantial, with exports not reaching 10% of what was traded. However, during the seventeenth century the trend changed compared to the sixteenth century and exports have a higher share in Veracruz trade, 9.1% versus 7.58%, respectively. The reasons for this dispute are that import trade from Seville, the fleets, was mainly composed of European manufactures of high value and quantity; while exports, raw materials for the most part of lower value, are compensated by the silver output. As we know, American colonial trade was characterized by a monopoly on European manufactures and by the lack of a local industry that generated its own merchandise.

Advertisement

6. Evolution and stages of global revenue

At the beginning of the reign of Philip II, the almojarifazgo raised in the port of Seville amounted to between 54,000 and 62,000 pesos per year. By the middle of the seventeenth century, this reached 600,000 ([18], p. 109). In Veracruz, between 1568 and 1571, 322,899 pesos were raised ([30], p. 1)21; while in the mid seventeenth century (1646–1650) the figure reached 291,246 pesos ([30], pp. 18–19).22 The fact that the quantities were so unequal between the two centuries does not mean that there was a commercial or revenue superiority between one and the other. The characteristics of the evolution of the collection of the almojarifazgo in the Caja de Veracruz contradict this difference by its irregularity, which was influenced by the fleets. Thus we see that it was in the first 15 years of the seventeenth century that almost 40% of what was collected was concentrated. A symptomatic fact of this tax irregularity can be seen in the annual average, which we have set at 89,899.45 pesos, compared to the total collection (Figure 1).

Figure 1.

Almojarifazgo Real Caja de Veracruz (1573–1659). Annual distribution (in common gold pesos). Data extracted from Table 3 annexed at the end of the present work.

According to data from the annual collection of the almojarifazgo, in Veracruz we have established five different stages in Table 2.

ImportationExportation
QuinquenniosFlotasSueltosTotalFlotasSueltosTotalTotal
1573–1593558,836.5046,539.30605,375.8023,112.6014,150.5037,263.10642,638.90
1594–1598120,030.5015,740.30135,770.8030,075.205,179.3035,254.40171,025.20
1599–16152,241,184.20108,384.402,349,568.60135,022.9024,437.20159,460.102,509,028.70
1616–16351,048,877.9095,120.801,143,998.70185,191.9019,394.10204,586.001,348,584.60
1636–1650507,808.50215,304.00723,112.6030,905.008,269.8039,174.80762,287.40
Total4,476,737.60481,088.704,957,826.30404,307.6071,430.80475,738.405,433,564.80

Table 2.

Evaluation of the collection of the almojarifazgo tax at the port of Veracruz (1573-1650) by the tendency in homogeneous periods.

In common gold pesos. In the concept “Sueltos”, the name used in the handling of documentation. Included is the revenue from colonial, African and Sevillian commerce that were not connected to fleets, but rather ships that carried official documentation.

6.1 First stage of boom: (1587–1593)

After the epidemic of yellow fever, which ravaged New Spain during the years 1576 and 1580 and which left a lull in the economy of the viceroyalty ([22], pp. 67–86), there was a boom23 in the collection of the almojarifazgo and, therefore, of trade at the port of Veracruz.

In these 8 years the amount paid for this right amounted to 642,638.9 pesos, 11.83% of the total collected. Although fleet traffic was not constant, there was no arrival in 1587, 1589 and 1592, nor of departure in 1587, 1588, 1589 and 1593. 581,949.1 pesos, 90.56% were raised for this concept; while trade on the side lines only totaled 60,689.8 pesos (Figure 2).

Figure 2.

Almojarifazgo Caja Real de Veracruz (1573–1650). Distribution by quinquenios (in common gold pesos). Data extracted from Table 2.

At the time, The New Spain economy suffered a series of manufacturing shortages that, as we have explained above, were filled from Seville, such as Andalusian wine and oil. These imports were mostly intended for the population of European origin. The evolution of this traffic conditioned the development of intercolonial traffic, since Veracruz acted as a re-exporter of the leftover fleets towards the area of influence of its trade, the Caribbean.

6.2 First stage of crisis: (1594–1598)

The European policy of the Castilian Crown conditioned the evolution of commercial traffic between the two continents and between the same colonies. Thus the wars of the late sixteenth century with Holland and France, allied with England, would influence the traffic and the collection of almojarifazgo. Fleets suffered harassment by these countries and by pirates, some English. During this period we see how the volume and value of what was negotiated between Seville and Mexico was reduced, leading to a short term crisis.24 After the signing of the Treaty of Vervins (1598), this trend would change.

At this stage, collection is reduced to 171,025.2 pesos, 3.15% of what was entered in the Caja for the whole period, a quarter of the amount established in the previous stage. Of this figure 150,105.8 pesos came from intercontinental trade goods, 87.77%, 120,030.5 pesos from imports and 30,075.3 exports. The trend of intercolonial trade in the collection of these years is slightly higher than the previous ones, from 9.44 to 12.23%, 20,919.4 pesos, a third below that.

While the tax charge for inbound fleets and intercolonial trade was reduced, exports of the former saw a 30.13% increase over the previous stage, constituting the beginning of a phase of export expansion of Veracruz to the metropolis in the fleets, that would last until 1616.

6.3 Second stage of boom: (1599–1615)

The political problems that interfered with the normal development of intercontinental trade disappeared from 159925 the collection of almojarifazgo collected by the Caja de Veracruz shows an upward trend. The influx of fleets to New Spain was steadily reduced, except in 1607 when there was the presence of a Dutch fleet on the coasts of the Iberian Peninsula26, and instead an armadilla was sent with the necessary azogues for the New Spain mines and some merchandise.

The reality could well be another: the saturation of the markets. Already in 1606, there was a significant reduction in fleet tax collection compared to the previous year, from 240,837.9 pesos in 1605 to 69,643.5 pesos in 1606 and to 2,962.3 pesos in 1607. The Mexican Consulate argued that the dangers of navigation were a cause of this decrease.

In these 17 years a total of 2,509,028.7 pesos, 46.18% of the total were entered into the Caja. Of this amount, 94.7%, 2,376,207.1 pesos corresponded to intercontinental fleet trade, while the remaining 5.3% was collected from intercolonial trade.

Although the margin of share of intercolonial trade in income was less than in the previous stage, 5.3% versus 12.23%, the average annual value of intercolonial trade, increased by double, or 7813 pesos versus 3486.6. During these years, fleet trade eclipsed non-fleet commerce, even if the latter was prosperous.

6.4 Second stage of crisis: (1616–1635)

The saturation of colonial markets led to a reduction in imports from the metropolis. This fact caused Sevillian merchants to opt for cut-offs of colonial markets in order to be able to place their products. This undersupply favored alternative ways to alleviate manufacturing shortages, such as smuggling, the emergence of an indigenous industry capable of competing with imported products in fleets, or sourcing them through the Manila Galleon.27

This was reflected in the collection of almojarifazgo in Veracruz, which at this stage is reduced to 53.75% compared to the previous, 1,348,584.6 pesos, 24.82% of the total collected, of which 1,234,069.8 pesos correspond to intercontinental trade or 91.51%, and 114,514.9 pesos to intercolonial trade.

This decline in tax revenues was more noticeable in imports, which fell to 1,048,877.9 pesos; while exports on the other hand increased by 37.15%. This increase would confirm the good health of the New Spain economy.

6.5 Crisis: (1636–1650)

The depression produced in the previous stage was worsened by the changes in frequency of fleets, from annually to every two years.28 There were no entry fleets in the port of Veracruz in 1637, 1639, 1641, 1643, 1645 and 1649, nor were there departures between 1634 and 1638 and in 1640, 1642, 1644 and 1646. These absences would significantly lower the income of the port Caja, which in those fifteen years accounted for only 762,287.4 pesos, which represented 14.03% of the total and a reduction of 43.47% less.

The consequences of this decline in intercontinental commercial activity would affect, by half, the intercolonial exchange of the New Spain port in its exports. By contrast, imports from colonial markets increased by 126.35% because of the emergence of Venezuelan cocoa in New Spain and the ban on trade with Peru (Arcila, 1950, pp. 251–252; [31], p. 586; [32], p. 5). This activity raised this trade by 29.33%, compared to 8.49% during the previous period.

Advertisement

7. Conclusions

Colonial trade was taxed by several tariffs levied by the Real Caja, such as the avería, the duty of tons, the almirantazgo, the lonja, the consulado or the almojarifazgo, among the most important. The latter has served for the present study and for a later one in which we explained how the trade of the New Spain port of Veracruz functioned.

Taxes were collected by royal officials appointed by the Real Hacienda in all ports, creating Real Cajas. It was done from the ship records that merchants were obliged to keep. The information they give us is very rich. Not only does it inform the origin and destination of the boat, type and its master, but it also relates the different goods and their merchant, with their value and the tax paid. There were exemptions in the collection of almojarifazgo, either for political or economic reasons, of goods or ports, such as those of Cumaná, Margarita, Caracas, Rio Hacha, Nueva Andalucía, Cartagena, Puerto Rico or Havana. The stipulated high percentage of almojarifazgo encouraged cases of fraud and smuggling. However, the information provided by the documentation on almojarifazgo of the Real Caja de Veracruz shows us the trend of New Spain trade through the aforementioned port.

Although Veracruz was only a mere redistributor of the goods that were negotiated in the capital of the viceroyalty, all traffic with Spain and the rest of the American colonies of the Caribbean passed through their docks. This had an influence on the calculation of the value of the declared goods. At first, the average prices calculated in Veracruz were fictitious. For this reason, a different form of calculation was established in 1576, using the average price of its highest, average and lowest value of its value in Mexico.

During the period studied (1573–1650), 5,533,564.8 pesos were collected at the Real Caja de Veracruz for the concept of almojarifazgo. We have calculated that 91.2% came from import trade and the rest from export trade Table 3. This meant, according to our calculations, the value of goods exchanged at the port was 72,836,207 pesos.

YearInputOutputTotal
FlotasSueltosTotalFlotasSueltosTotal
1573964.3964.35084.5161.15245.66209.9
15872801.62801.6268.3268.33069.9
1588126,927.57776.1134,703.64842.44842.4139,546.0
158914,440.414,440.42233.62233.616,674.0
1590118,482.07313.5125,795.52899.32484.05383.3131,178.8
159167,303.53113.170,416.68614.41972.010,586.481,003.0
15925019.35019.36514.4800.97315.312,334.5
1593246,123.55111.0251,234.51388.31388.3252,622.8
159480,333.03119.083,452.010,555.8364.610,920.494,372.4
159539,697.52568.542,266.08208.81682.69891.452,157.4
15964016.34016.35744.41052.86797.210,813.4
15972500.62500.65566.31372.36938.59439.1
15983535.93535.9707.0707.04242.9
1599205,662.44656.8210,319.23975.51335.45310.9215,630.0
1600168,578.05336.6173,914.611,582.52828.114,410.6188,325.3
1601110,862.19029.0119,891.112,935.02254.315,189.3135,080.4
1602156,331.06337.8162,668.89067.61886.810,954.4173,623.1
1603101,031.88233.3109,265.010,958.51649.812,608.3121,873.3
1604204,846.07352.3212,198.310,651.61814.612,466.3224,664.5
1605240,837.97054.5247,892.44457.81516.15973.9253,866.3
160669,642.56318.375,960.82348.91124.13473.079,433.8
16072,962.36863.69825.912,425.61261.413,687.023,512.9
1608293,263.99188.5302,452.44574.51762.36336.8308,789.1
1609157,472.15911.0163,383.15533.4916.86450.1169,833.3
161044,837.45134.449,971.85094.6826.45921.055,892.8
161175,833.47096.582,929.96607.51203.17810.690,740.5
161279,082.34014.583,096.87456.11500.48956.592,053.3
1613100,806.35341.9106,148.19693.11019.910,713.0116,861.1
1614105,920.35671.0111,591.37308.8919.48228.1119,819.4
1615123,214.84844.6128,059.410,351.9618.510,970.4139,029.8
161652,942.02546.655,488.65819.8619.66439.461,928.0
161763,053.33039.166,092.47165.0621.27786.273,878.6
161872,956.83100.976,057.69234.9552.89787.685,845.3
1919116,363.53079.6119,443.112,176.8586.612,763.4132,206.5
162094,834.44140.898,975.111,463.5885.612,349.1111,324.3
162186,818.05551.692,369.610,664.9944.611,609.5103,979.1
162262,353.02454.164,807.115,626.11032.616,658.881,465.9
1622–162356,686.04622.061,308.019,133.01192.020,325.081,633.0
1623–162458,622.06839.065,461.014,724.01781.016,505.081,966.0
1624–16255813.05813.013,611.01137.014,748.020,561.0
1626–162790,269.010,863.0101,132.012,263.02155.014,418.0115,550.0
1627–1628129,885.08778.0138,663.011,693.01419.013,112.0151,775.0
1630–163177,254.010,067.087,321.011,140.01352.012,492.099,813.0
1631–163357,127.013,616.070,743.030,477.02969.033,446.0104,189.0
1634–163529,714.010,610.040,324.02146.02146.042,470.0
163681,783.0965.082,748.0236.0236.082,984.0
163711,067.011,067.0754.0754.011,821.0
163880,518.415,924.996,443.3492.9492.996,936.1
16394795.44795.45547.4429.95977.310,772.6
164088,625.410,463.199,088.5543.4543.499,631.9
16418490.38490.39331.0446.49777.418,267.6
164248,385.613,186.861,572.4554.8554.862,127.1
164320,366.020,366.05151.3405.45556.625,922.6
164432,652.820,495.453,148.1760.1760.153,908.3
164511,531.511,531.55515.01140.16655.118,186.6
164671,670.028,827.5100,497.5307.1307.1100,804.6
164726,785.918,408.645,194.52812.9553.63366.548,561.0
164845,783.515,766.961,550.41146.4342.01488.463,038.8
164916,556.116,556.1753.8661.01414.817,970.9
165031,604.018,459.650,063.6647.4643.11290.551,354.1
Total4,476,737.6481,088.74,957,826.3404,307.671,430.8475,738.45,433,564.8

Table 3.

Annual revenue from the almojarifazgo tax from the port of Veracruz (1573–1650).

In common gold pesos. The concept “Sueltos” includes the collection of colonial, African and Sevillian commerce, apart from fleets.

Based on the evolution of the collection we have established five well differentiated stages, two of boom and three of crises, the last of them being the one that was felt the most by the economic and political situation of Spain. The first boom stage, between 1588 and 1599, arises as a result of a commercial take-off following the yellow fever epidemic in New Spain (1576–1580) and is characterized by the introduction of European goods for consumption by Spaniards and their re-export to other Caribbean markets. Then there is a crisis phase, between 1594 and 1598, of reduction of collection in the course of the European wars of Spain and that will have a positive consequence in the increase in trade towards the metropolis, with an increase of 30.13%. A second moment of boom (1599–1615) appears with peace in Europe, in which a regularity is established in the predominance of the fleet trade over the rest of the Veracruz trade. Then there is a second and long stage of crisis in the collection (1616–1635) caused by the saturation of the New Spain markets and that the Sevillian traders cause more criticism by deliberately undersupplying traffic. Thus, smuggling would arise and the development of an internal, local industry, which would supply the New Spain market. The collection shows us a reduction in imports, but not exports. Finally, this crisis would be exacerbated between 1635 and 1650 because the annual fleets become biannual. This was a major disruption of incoming almojarifazgo in the port of Veracruz, especially that originated by colonial exports, which are reduced by half. The revenue of colonial imports, on the other hand, would double with an increase of 126.35%. We leave the study of the different markets, goods and their negotiated value for future work.

Advertisement

Acknowledgments

My acknowledgment to Maria Ruth Giesbrecht for her support and collaboration in the translation of this work.

Advertisement

Documentary sources

  1. Archivo General de Indias (A.G.I.).

    • Audiencia de México, Leg. 351. Cartas y expedientes de oficiales reales de Veracruz.

    • Contaduría. Caja Real de Veracruz. Leg. 878. Cuentas de Real Hacienda de lo remitido a España desde 1568 a fin de junio de 1573 con los comprobantes del cargo.

    • Contaduría. Caja Real de Veracruz. Leg. 879. Cuentas de Real Hacienda desde 1587 a 1591.

    • Contaduría. Caja Real de Veracruz. Leg. 880. Cuentas de Real Hacienda desde junio de 1590 a diciembre de 1594.

    • Contaduría. Caja Real de Veracruz. Leg. 881. Cuentas de Real Hacienda desde 17 de diciembre de 1594 a fin de 1599.

    • Contaduría. Caja Real de Veracruz. Leg. 882. Cuentas de Real Hacienda desde 1°de enero de 1600 a 14 de octubre de 1609.

    • Contaduría. Caja Real de Veracruz. Leg, 883. Cuentas de Real Hacienda desde 14 de octubre de 1609 a 3 de septiembre de 1622.

    • Contaduría. Caja Real de Veracruz. Leg. 884B. Cuentas de Real Hacienda desde 6 de septiembre de 1622 a 8 de agosto de 1637.

    • Contaduría. Caja Real de Veracruz. Leg. 884A. Cuentas de Real Hacienda desde 6 de septiembre de 1622 a 8 de agosto de 1637.

    • Contaduría. Caja Real de Veracruz. Leg. 885A. Cuentas de Real Hacienda desde 9 de agosto de 1637 a 4 de octubre de 1646.

    • Contaduría. Caja Real de Veracruz. Leg. 885B. Cuentas de Real Hacienda desde 5 de octubre de 1646 a 27 de noviembre de 1653.

    • Consulado. Libro I. Libros de las Juntas y acuerdos del Consulado.

References

  1. 1. Chaunu P. Serie: Filosofía y Letras, Sevilla, Sevilla y América, siglos XVI y XVII. Publicaciones de la Universidad de Sevilla; 1983. p. 65
  2. 2. Lorenzo Sanz E. Comercio de España con América en la época de Felipe II (Tomo II). Valladolid: Institución Cultural Simancas; 1980
  3. 3. Yun B. Imperio español, entre la monarquía compuesta y el colonialismo mercantil. Metodologías, contextos institucionales y perspectivas para el estudio de la fiscalidad y la movilización de recursos. In: Martínez P, Sánchez E, Souto M, editors. La fiscalidad New Spain en el imperio español. Conceptualizaciones, proyectos y contradicciones. México: Instituto de Investigaciones Dr. José María Luis Mora/Universidad Nacional Autónoma de México, Instituto de Investigaciones Históricas; 2015. pp. 29-67
  4. 4. García-Abasolo A. Martín Enríquez y la reforma de 1568 en Nueva España. Sevilla: Diputación Provincial; 1983
  5. 5. Gil Blanco E. El almojarifazgo como índice de interpretación del comercio del puerto de Veracruz, 1600-1622. Estudios de Historia Social y Económica de América. 1986;2:89-119
  6. 6. Gil Blanco E. El tráfico del puerto de Veracruz en 1572. Estudios de Historia Social y Económica de América. 1990;7:19-26
  7. 7. Gil Blanco E. Auge y crisis del tráfico comercial veracruzano visto a través de la cuenta de almojarifazgo, 1573-1650 (Tesis doctoral inédita). Alcalá de Henares: Universidad de Alcalá; 1993
  8. 8. Miranda J. España y Nueva España en la época de Felipe II. México: Instituto de Historia, Universidad Nacional Autónoma de México; 1962
  9. 9. Ayala M. Diccionario de gobierno y legislación de Indias. Madrid: Ediciones Cultura Hispánica; 1988
  10. 10. Moreyra Paz-Soldán M. Estudios sobre el tráfico marítimo en la época colonial. Lima: Libreria e Imprenta Gil; 1944
  11. 11. Salas Almela L. Nobleza y fiscalidad en la Ruta de las Indias: el emporio señorial de Sanlúcar de Barrameda (1576-1641). Anuario de Estudios Americanos. 2007, (julio-septiembre);64:13-60
  12. 12. Salas Almela L. Los antepuertos de Sevilla: señorío, comercio y fiscalidad en la Carrera de Indias (s. XVI). In: Vila Vilar E, Lacueva Muñoz J, editors. Mirando las dos orillas: intercambios mercantiles, sociales y culturales entre Andalucía y América. Sevilla: Fundación Buenas Letras; 2012. pp. 105-127
  13. 13. Tepaske JJ, Klein HS. Ingresos y egresos de la Real Hacienda de Nueva España. México: Instituto Nacional de Antropología e Historia; 1988
  14. 14. Celaya Nández Y. La cesión de un derecho de la Real Hacienda: la administración del impuesto de la alcabala novohispana en el siglo XVII. Tres estudios de caso. In: América Latina en la Historia Económica. 2010, enero-junio. pp. 91-125
  15. 15. Céspedes del Castillo G. La avería en el comercio de Indias. Escuela de Estudios Hispano-Americanos: Sevilla; 1945. p. 187
  16. 16. Hausberger B, Ibarra A. Comercio y poder en América colonial: los consulados de comerciantes, siglos XVII-XIX. Madrid, Frankfurt del Main y México: Iberoamericana/Vervuert/Instituto Mora
  17. 17. Antúnez RA. Memorias históricas sobre la legislación y gobierno del comercio de los españoles con sus Colonias en las Indias Occidentales. Madrid: Imprenta de Sancha; 1797
  18. 18. Hamilton EJ. The decline of Spain. In: The Economic History Review. Vol. VIII. 1938
  19. 19. León Borja D, Szasdi Nagy A. El comercio del cacao en Guayaquil. Revista de Historia de América, LVII. 1964:57-58
  20. 20. Vila Vilar E. Historia de Puerto Rico: 1600-1650. Sevilla: Consejo superior de investigaciones científicas, Escuela de Estudios Hispano-Americanos; 1974
  21. 21. Borah W. Comercio y navegación entre México y Perú́ en el siglo XVI. México: Instituto Mexicano de Comercio Exterior; 1975
  22. 22. García de León A. Tierra adentro, mar en fuera. El puerto de Veracruz y su litoral a Sotavento, 1519-1821. México, D.F.: F.C.E. Universidad Veracruzana; 2014
  23. 23. Martínez P, Sánchez E, Souto M. La fiscalidad novohispana en el imperio español. Conceptualizaciones, proyectos y contradicciones. México: Instituto de Investigaciones Dr. José María Luis Mora/Universidad Nacional Autónoma de México, Instituto de Investigaciones Históricas; 2015
  24. 24. Arcila E. Hacienda y comercio de Venezuela en el siglo XVI. Caracas: Banco Central de Venezuela; 1983
  25. 25. Borrego MC. Cartagena de Indias en el siglo XVI: contribución a la conmemoración del V Centenario del Descubrimiento. Sevilla: Escuela de Estudios Hispano-Americanos; 1983
  26. 26. Valle Pavón G. Gestión del derecho de alcabalas y conflictos por la representación corporativa: la transformación de la normatividad electoral del Consulado de México en el siglo XVII. In: Hausberger B, Ibarra A, editors. Comercio y poder en América colonial: los consulados de comerciantes, siglos XVII-XIX. Madrid, Frankfurt del Main y México: Iberoamericana/Vervuert/Instituto Mora; 2003. pp. 41-72
  27. 27. Fuentes García A. Los ingenios de azúcar en La Habana del siglo XVII (1650-1700): estructura y mano de obra. Revista de Historia Económica, IX. 1991, invierno;1
  28. 28. Haring CH. Comercio y navegación entre España y las Indias en la época de los Habsburgo. México: Fondo de Cultura Económica; 1979
  29. 29. Gil Blanco E. Interpretación del comercio de un puerto colonial novohispano durante un periodo de crisis, Veracruz (1587-1650). Estudios de Historia Social y Económica de América. 1997;14:75-123
  30. 30. Sánchez E. La mirada fiscal sobre el comercio interno: las alcabalas novohispanas. In: Martínez P, Sánchez E, Souto M, editors. La fiscalidad novohispana en el imperio español. Conceptualizaciones, proyectos y contradicciones. México: Instituto de Investigaciones Dr. José María Luis Mora/Universidad Nacional Autónoma de México, Instituto de Investigaciones Históricas; 2015. pp. 165-187
  31. 31. Calderón F. Historia económica de la Nueva España en Tiempos de los Austrias. México: Fondo de Cultura Económica; 1988
  32. 32. Jumar FA. El comercio atlántico de Río de La Plata, 1680-1778. El circuito legal español. Las fuentes utilizadas y su tratamiento. América Latina en la Historia Económica. 2004, enero-junio:11-36

Notes

  • Merced given in Burgos on 6 May 1497 and ratified by the Consejo de Indias. We also use as a source the book of Antúnez, Memorias histórcas…, although it is not a very reliable source, but it includes tax legislation and other issues relating to existing regulations in the tax season.
  • This Real Cédula refers to the collection of the almojarifazgo from intercontinental trade and was issued on June 24, 1566, received by the Real Audiencia de México on September 21 of the same year, sent to Veracruz the following day and settled in the books of the Real Caja of the port by treasurer Rodrigo Fránquez on August 27, 1573. Archivo General de Indias (hereinafter A.G.I.). Contaduría. Real Caja de Veracruz. Leg. 878. Recop. Leyes de Indias... Book VIII. Tit. XV. Law I.
  • This Real Provision establishes the almojarifazgo for intercolonial trade. Its development is produced by the Cédula of October 11, 1570. In New Spain, Viceroy Enríquez imposed it on Provision of April 6, 1571 given in Mexico City on September 30, 1571. A.G.I. Contaduría. Caja Real de Veracruz. Leg. 878. Recop. Leyes de Indias… Lib. VIII. Tit. XV. Law I.
  • A.G.I. Contaduría. Caja Real de Veracruz. Leg. 878. Transfer of Her Majesty’s Card where the scareping rights of the goods of Castile are sent to collect to X per cent and the wines to XX.
  • A.G.I. Contaduría. Caja Real de Veracruz. Leg. 878. The collection of the new almojarifazgo rights at two and a half percent.
  • Cédula of January 25, 1567.
  • Goods shipped by the Crown have been exempt from 1507. April 27, 1574, ratified by the Cédulas of September 14, 1613 and December 12, 1619. Recop. Leyes de Indias... Lib. VIII. Tit. XV. Law XXVI.
  • December 15, 1531 for clergy and February 28, 1543 for the rest of the passengers. Recop. Leyes de Indias...Lib. VIII. Tit. XV. Laws XXVIII and XXIX.
  • November 4, 1548 contained in the Recop. Leyes de Indias... Lib. VIII. Tit. XV. Law XXVII.
  • Real Cédulas of December 8, 1533, November 8, 1539 and February 11, 1540.
  • Ordenanzas of 1554 and Cédula of December 22, 1579.
  • A.G.I. Contaduría, Caja Real de Veracruz, Leg. 878.
  • April 21 and 27 1574.Recop. Leyes de Indias... Lib. VIII. Tit. XV. Laws VIII and XIX.
  • Cédulas of December 28, 1568 and March 9, 1620. Recop. Leyes de Indias..., Lib. VIII. Tit. XV. Law I.
  • Recop. Leyes de Indias... Lib. VIII. Tit. XV. Law V.
  • Cédulas of April 16 and August 4, 1550, May 10, 1554, August 24, 1619 and January 23, 1627. Recop. Leyes de Indias. Lib. VIII. Tit. XV. Law V.
  • Real Card of December 22, 1579.
  • A.G.I. Contaduría. Caja Real de Veracruz. Leg. 878.
  • Existing documentary gaps are from June 14, to December 17, 1594, from May 6, to August 31, 1601, from May 17 to November 29, 1602, from June to October 31, 1607, from July to October 1627, from August, 9 1628 to November 7, 1630, from November 4, 1632 to August 6, 1633 and from September 5, 1636 to August 11, 1637.
  • A.G.I. Contaduría. Caja Real de Veracruz. Legs. 878, 879, 880, 881, 882, 883, 884B, 884A, 885A, and 885B.
  • A.G.I. Contaduría. Caja Real de Veracruz. Leg. 878, branch 1, from Septembre of 1568 until June of 1571.
  • A.G.I. Contaduría. Caja Real de Veracruz. Leg. 885B, branch 7, from October to December 31, 1650.
  • A.G.I. Contaduría. Caja Real de Veracruz. Legs. 878, branch 3, from August 11, 1572 to June 30, 1573; 879, branches 1 y 2, from June, 1587 to June 13, 1591; y 880, branches 1 a 4, from June 30, 1590 to June 14, 1594.
  • A.G.I. Contaduría. Caja Real de Veracruz. Legs. 880, branch 4, from October 20, 1592 to June 14, 1594; y 881, branches 1 to 5, from October 19, 1594 to January 1, 1600.
  • A.G.I. Contaduría. Caja Real de Veracruz. Legs. 881, branch 4, from May 26, 1598 to January 1, 1600; 882, branches 1 a 11, from May 7, 1600 to October 14, 1609; and 883, branches 1 to 7, from October 14, 1609 to June 12, 1616.
  • A.G.I. Consulado. Libro I. Folios. 162–165.
  • A.G.I. Contaduría. Caja Real de Veracruz. Legs. 883, branches 7 a 14, from June 11, 1615 to October 14, 1622; 884B, branches 1 a 9, from September 5, 1622 to September 14, 1627; and 884A, branches 1 to 10, from September 14, 1627 to September 4, 1636.
  • A.G.I. Contaduría. Caja Real de Veracruz. Legs. 884A, branch 10, from November 19, 1634 to September 4, 1636; 885A, branches 1 to 6, from August 12, 1637 to October 4, 1646; and 885B, branch 7, from October 5, 1646 hasta December 5, 1650.

Written By

Emiliano Gil-Blanco

Submitted: 27 July 2019 Reviewed: 24 September 2019 Published: 12 March 2020