Open access peer-reviewed chapter

The Effect of Taxation, Specialization, and Entrepreneurial Activities on International Trading

By Er'el Granot

Submitted: December 9th 2017Reviewed: February 1st 2018Published: February 28th 2018

DOI: 10.5772/intechopen.74751

Downloaded: 180

Abstract

In this chapter, a generalization of the Ricardian model of international trading is presented. Unlike the original Ricardian analysis, the presented model takes into account the producers entrepreneurial activities, their specialization factor (the improvement factor in production due to specialization) and the countries taxes (tariffs). The main result of this model is that for a given entrepreneurial activity culture and a given specialization factor, there exists a critical taxation level, above which specialization and all entrepreneurial activities are suppressed and international commerce is ceased. The transition from a working international market to a trade-less one is an abrupt one and resembles a phase transition.

Keywords

  • entrepreneurship
  • international trading
  • specialization
  • unstable markets
  • entrepreneurial behavior
  • entrepreneur
  • iterative economic processes
  • Austrian school of economic

1. Introduction

One of the successes of the classical economics revolution was to rebut the mercantilist tradition that holds the premises that trading can be harmful for the trading countries. The success was not merely an academic one; as a result of this revolution, Britain, Europe and eventually the whole world experienced a great economic boom.

The revolution was based on three important realizations:

  1. The market does not prefer specialization due to the differences in the inborn merits of humans. Specialization itself makes the market much more efficient. Even if initially people have the same general merits, they can still specialize and optimize the market.

  2. The market is not a zero sum game. Both sides (countries), in any free transaction, buyers and sellers, benefit from trading.

  3. Similarly, trading improves the condition of (international) producers, regardless of the efficiency differences between them.

Despite the fact that these realizations were initial ingredients in the classical revolution, the classical economists themselves did not integrate them in a single theory. While Smith talked only on the first and second realizations [1], Ricardo in the law of comparative advantage disregards the effect of specialization and focused on the third realization [2].

It is a common mistake to assume that Ricardo’s law of comparative advantage does take specialization into account; however, it does not. It assumes that the producer’s efficiency is independent of his specialization level [2, 3, 4, 5, 6].

During the marginalist revolution [7] in the 1870s, the world of economics experienced another split of visions: the majority of the economics community adopted the Marshallian-Walrasian tradition [8, 9], which based their studies on equilibrium analysis. A minority of the economists’ community, which was known as the Austrian School [10, 11, 12], based their analysis on methodological individualism, that is, they based their approach on the acting entrepreneur [13, 14, 15].

This approach was alien to the main stream, where the Marshallian-Walrasian tradition was rooted, especially after the work of Knight [16], which based the market on perfect knowledge. In a perfect knowledge market, there is no room for entrepreneurial activity.

Uncertainty is the playing ground in which the entrepreneur acts. Both schools recognize the fact that the market tend to an equilibrium state, but the realization is different. Perfect knowledge cannot exist in a disequilibrium market. It is much more difficult to explain the equilibria existence in the presence of perpetual entrepreneurial activities. The Austrian economists explained that the entrepreneurs are not a disruptive element, but rather a stabilizing one, since the entrepreneur recognizes any deviation from equilibrium as an entrepreneurial opportunity. Consequently, his entrepreneurial act stabilizes the market and helps in keeping it at a semi-equilibrium state.

The main problem is that from the Austrian’s writing, it seems as if the entrepreneur has some special merits [13, 14, 15], which helps him recognize the discrepancy in the market, which he can mitigate with his entrepreneurial activity. However, since it was not clear what this merits are, they never demonstrate it.

In [17], it was demonstrated that entrepreneurial activity can be totally random. No insight is required for a successful entrepreneurial act. In fact, the profit and loss mechanism along with some memory of past transaction is sufficient to navigate the entrepreneurial activity in the right direction to mitigate the deviations from equilibrium.

International trade requires specialization, and specialization is an entrepreneurial activity. The producer risks himself in specializing. While specializing, the producer compromises, for he has to change his production point, at least temporarily, to a worse one. His analysis teaches him that there is a good chance that eventually, after trading, his condition will be better; however, by no means, it is a simple decision to specialize. It is an entrepreneurial decision.

Taxes and regulations suppress entrepreneurial activity, but they operate in a different manner. Regulations prohibit some activities, while taxes reduce the motivation to make them. Therefore, trade, international and domestic, requires entrepreneurial activity and specialization, while taxes suppress the three.

There is a delicate connection between these components. For example, when entrepreneurial activities increase (either by educational activities or regulations’ reductions), specialization and trading are encouraged despite the suppressive effect of some taxes.

Any theory of international trading that does not include entrepreneurial and specialization ([3]) along with taxes cannot be regarded as a complete theory. In this chapter, we propose a model, which integrate these components into a single model, which yields simple relations.

2. The effect of taxation

When two traders interact and exchange a certain good, their status is presented initially as a point in the commodities space. The exchange itself is presented by arrows, which oriented toward the final states (final points in the commodities space—see Figure 1). When there are no taxes, then the two arrows are identical in terms of length and slope.

Figure 1.

The ‘x’ and ‘o’ represent the two traders’ possession before the trading transaction. The arrows represent the transaction itself. On the left, there are no taxes, and therefore the arrows are parallel, while on the right, due to taxes, the arrows are tilted toward the origin.

However, when taxes are applied, then the head of the arrows is drawn toward the origin. It does not matter whether the taxes are collected in terms of commodity A or commodity B. The buyer ‘sees’ a higher price, while the seller ‘sees’ a lower one.

In Figure 1, the collected taxes are 20% of the exchanging commodities. In the figure, it is assumed that both buyers and sellers pay the same tax level.

In the Marshallian-Walrasian tradition, the price of commodities is determined by the intersection of the demand and supply curves [18]. This is a stationary equilibrium scenario.

In general, the curves are unknown and can have an arbitrary shape (see, e.g. [19]); however, at the vicinity of the intersection, they can be approximated by a linear curve, that is, the demand curve (at the vicinity of the intersection) can be written as

Dp=DpdE1

while the supply curve can be written as

Sp=Sps,E2

where D,S,dand sare independent of the price p.

When taxes are applied, the price increases by a factor, which for convenience matters will be written as an exponent, et(which is equivalent to a tax of 100t%), that is, the demand curve decreases faster

Dp=Dpetd.E3

Similarly, in the supply curve, the price decreases by et(again, it is assumed that the taxes are equal for buying and selling), that is

Sp=Spets.E4

The intersection occurs when

Dp=Sp=DSDsSdet+SdDsetsdet+dset=DScoshα+tθcoshα+tE5

where DSexpθ, dsexpα, at the price level

p=DSdssinhθcoshα+t.E6

Therefore, the market price decreases, because taxes reduce the attractiveness of the commodity, while the consumer price increases to

peτ=DSdssinhθexptcoshα+t.E7

Clearly, trading is suppressed since cosh is a convex function, the denominator of Eq. (5) increases faster than the numerator. That is, Eq. (5) decreases when taxation increases.

However, even analyses, which consider taxation, still lack two important ingredients: specializations and entrepreneurship.

Following [6, 17], assume that the production possibility frontiers (PPFs) of two producers are

a1A1+b1B11E8

and

a2A2+b2B21E9

respectively. That is, the maximum numbers of units of commodities A and B that the first producer can produce are A1and B1, respectively, and the production of the second one is bounded by A2and B2, respectively, while a1and b1are the number of units the first producer chooses to produce, and similarly, a2and b2are the number of units the second one produces.

In this case, trading occurs provided the price pΔA/ΔB, which is the ratio between exchanged commodities ΔAunits of A for ΔBunits of B, obeys

A2B2<p<A1B1.E10

However, if taxes are introduced, the condition for trading is less flexible

A2B2<pexpt<pexpt<A1B1orA2B2expt<p<A1B1expt.E11

Therefore, trading is possible provided the tax level is lower than

t<lnA1B1B2A2E12

However, this analysis ignores, again, specialization.

3. The effect of specialization

In case the producers can specialize, the PPF becomes a convex curve. Therefore, if a manufacture specializes by doubling the time he invests in the production of a certain product, the resultant production increases by a factor, which is larger than 2.

Following [6, 17], we choose the following PPF, which takes specialization into account

aAα+bBβ=1E13

The smaller the exponents α,βthe higher is the level of specialization.

Hereinafter, to simplify the analysis, we take that the specialization level in both commodities is the same, that is, α=β. Therefore, we focus on a PPF of the form

aAβ+bBβ=1,E14

in which case the relation between the specialization factor F and the exponent α=βis simply [6].

F=21/β1,E15

which means that the ratio between the production productivities in the case of full specialization (free trading) and no specialization (no trading) is F=21/β1[6].

Since the units, by which the commodities are measured, are arbitrary, then without the loss of generality, we can replace the parameters to the dimensionless coordinates ξa/Aand ηb/B. Therefore, Eq. (14) reads

ξβ+ηβ=1.E16

Furthermore, it is convenient to change the coordinates into radial ones, that is

ξ2+η2=r2,E17
ξ=rcosφ,andE18
η=rsinφ.E19

Then, instead of the Cartesian relation η=1ξβ1/β, a radial one emerges

rφ=1sinβφ+cosβφ1/β,E20

and due to the symmetry of the problem, it is more convenient to use the deviation from the 45° angle, that is, we take the angle δ=φπ/4, in which case

rδ=1sinβπ/4+δ+cosβπ/4+δ1/β=2cosδ+sinδβ+cosδsinδβ1/βE21

For small angles, Eq. (21) can be approximated by

rδr0+1β2r0δ2E22

where

r0rδ=0=21/21/βE23

is the distance to the origin.

Equations (21) and (22) allow one to evaluate the specialization ras a function of the entrepreneurial activity δ, because δis the deviation from the (pre-trade) optimal point.

Therefore, if any single producer/entrepreneur can decide in changing his working point from r0δ=0to r±δ±δ, then the producers’ population splits into two sub-groups: one at rδ+δand the other at rδδ.

These two populations start trading with a price, which in the ξηspace is equal to 1 (which is B/Ain the abspace). Therefore, after trading they both converge to the point rδcosδ0, which is more favorable point in the preference ranking of the producers (since this point is perpendicular to the PPF) (Figure 2).

Figure 2.

Trading in the presence of specialization and taxation. Without specialization, the production point is ξ = η = 1 / 4 (the diamond in the left figure). The curved line is the PPF. With specialization, the producers’ production point splits into the two ‘+’, while trading (represented by arrows) improves the status of both producers to the point represented by ‘o’ (in the right figure). Taxation tilts the arrows to a worse position, which can even eliminate the specialization beneficial effect (the right figure).

When taxes are applied, the final point (after trading, AF) is closer to the origin (0,0), that is, rAFδ<rδcosδr01+1β2δ2. Clearly, when the taxes are high so that rAFδr0, then the motivation for entrepreneurship, specialization, and trading vanishes.

This event occurs when the change in the arrows slope, which is the normalized change in the price Δp, is equal to

Δp=2rδcosδr0rδsinδ1βδ,E24

However, the normalized change in the price is exactly the tax level, that is, the tax level beyond which no trading is possible (tc) is equal to

tc1βδ.E25

Eq. (25) is the main result of this chapter, for it integrates taxation (t) specialization (β) and entrepreneurship (δ) in a simple relation.

Now since (Eq. (15)) β=11+log2F,then we can formulate an expression which relates the entrepreneurial parameter δand the specialization factor Fto the critical taxation level tc:

tcδ1+1/log2FE26

This equation can be rewritten to evaluate the critical specialization factor, which is required to initiate trading for a given level of entrepreneurship and taxation, namely

Fc=2δ/t11.E27

This is the specialization factor required to overcome the suppression effect of the countries’ tariffs, the graph of which is presented in Figure 3.

Figure 3.

The dependence of the critical specialization factor as a function of the ratio between δ and the tax level t.

Since without specialization, the production frontier is a/F+b/B=1/F, then δcan be easily replaced with a corresponding variation in the real commodity units Δaand Δb, namely

δ=8FΔaA=8FΔbAE28

and therefore, the critical taxation can be written as a function of the real change in production, caused by the entrepreneurial decision, that is,

tc8FΔa/A1+1/log2F=8FΔb/B1+1/log2F.E29

4. Perpetual entrepreneurial activities

In real markets (international and domestic) where the traders are also producers, as was explained above and in [17], the producers take much risk when they decide on the amount of good to produce. In this case, a producer may find himself in a worse condition. Any change in his production habits is a temporary deterioration in his preference ranking.

Clearly, the only information he has on the other producers’ preferences is the market price, which in our units is approximately p = 1.

Let us assume that all producers are identical; therefore, they all have the same production frontier, then the nth producers can be characterized by the Cartesian pair ξnηnor the radial pair δnrn. Similarly, they all have the same preference ranking matrix Rξη. This two-parameter function (matrix in the discrete case) can be regarded as the utility function of the state ξη; however, when the parameters ξηare discrete, then a ranking function is consistent with the Austrian school as well ([6, 20]). Therefore, we prefer to use the term ‘preference ranking’ matrix instead of ‘utility’ function.

Initially therefore, the point with the highest preference ranking is ξn=ηn=r0/2, that is,

Rn0=Rr0/2r0/2=maxη<ηξnRξη,E30

which is equivalent in radial coordinates to r=r0and δ=0(for all n).

When trading begins, each one of the producers uses the current market price to evaluate future profits from possible production alternatives. This is a perpetual process [21], which consists of multiple iterations.

Let m represents the iteration number. Initially, m = 0.

In any iteration, the market price is first determined. Let the market price of the mth iteration be pm.

Furthermore, it is assumed that the state of the nth producer at the mth iteration is characterized by the two parameters δnmrnm, and therefore their state in the (m + 1)th iteration can be written

δnm+1=δnm+ΔδnmE31
rnm+1=rδnm+1E32

where rxis function (21), and Δδnmare random variations that are subject to the constrains

π4δnmπ4.E33

These states can easily be transformed back to Cartesian coordinate by

ξnm=rnmcosδnm.E34
ηnm=rnmsinδnmE35

Now, all the possible states that are reachable by trading ξηmust obey

ηηnm+1τpmξξnm+1,E36

where τ=expsgnδt=exptδ>0exptδ<0is the taxation effect on the price level (note that it has the opposite effect on buyers and sellers).

If among all these points (which are reachable by trading), there is at least one point, whose preference ranking is larger than the previous iteration ranking Rξnmηnm, that is,

Rξnmηnm<maxηηnm+1τpmξξnm+1RξηE37

Then, ξnm+1ηnm+1(or equivalently δnm+1rnm+1) is chosen as the next iteration production point, otherwise (if the ranking is lower than the previous one) then this trial point is rejected and the previous production point is kept.

Clearly, this process determines the production decisions, and it does not include the trading results. In principle, nothing assures the entrepreneurial producer that he will reach a higher ranking point. This is a risk that he takes.

5. Simulations

We simulate the market with N entrepreneurs, which their entrepreneurial activities in every iteration Δδare randomly selected with a uniform distribution, namely their probability density satisfies

PΔδ=x=1/Φx<Φ/20else.E38

All entrepreneurs have the same PPF with a specialization exponent of β=1/2(which is equivalent to a specialization factor of F = 2).

We begin with zero taxes and N = 40,000 entrepreneurs. These entrepreneurs can be distributed among different countries provided there are no tariffs.

In this case, the initial market is totally unstable, and in the very first trading iterations, the market splits into two distinct population sub-groups: one group produces more units of commodity B than units of commodity A (for which δ>0) and vice versa for the second group (for which δ<0). The problem is totally symmetric, and there are no drifts (unlike [17], where the drifts seem to be a simulation artefact).

In Figure 4, two histograms of the population as a function of the iterations number (the time) are presented. As can be seen, the population indeed splits into two population sub-groups.

Figure 4.

The population distribution as a function of the iteration number (temporal histogram). The darker the color, the higher is the number of producers. The instability is clearly shown as the population splits into two sub-groups of specialized producers-buyers and sellers. The dashed curves correspond to functions (39) and (40).

Therefore, half of the iterations, on average, do not improve specialization, because they work in the wrong direction. The average improvement, among those that do contribute, is Φ/4(the average between zero and Φ/2); therefore, the specialization angles increase linearly with the iteration number m:

δm=±Φm/8Φm/8<π/4±π/4elseE39

where m stands for the iteration number and the upper/lower signs of ‘±’ stand for the buyers/sellers population group, respectively. These equations are presented in the left plot of Figure 4 by the dashed lines for the simulation parameter Φ=0.015Rad.

Similarly, we can clearly see the ‘parabolic’ rise in the specialization factor r (the right figure). The dashed curve corresponds to the function

rm=1/2cosΦm/8+cosΦm/4Φm/8<π/41elseE40

which is a derivation of Eq. (21) for β=1/2.

When transaction taxes are applied (i.e. tariffs in international trading), then the system can be quasi stable.

In the next simulation, the tax levels are varied. For every tax level, 500 iterations were applied on a market of N = 400 participants (which can represent 400 countries). The results are presented in Figures 5 and 6. The transition between the specialization domain (high r) and non-specialization domain (low r) is clearly seen. Below the critical taxation level, the market experiences a split, and full specialization is reached when the standard deviation of δconverges to σδπ/4, while the mean specialization parameter r converges to r1. However, when the taxes are higher than the critical level tcΦ/4(note that β=1/2), specialization and trading are totally suppressed. The transition is extremely sharp and it resembles a phase transition.

Figure 5.

The impact of taxation on the standard deviation of δ , left figure, and the mean value of r, right figure (both are a measure of specialization) for the entrepreneurial parameter Φ = 0.03 Rad after 500 iterations and N = 400 participants (entrepreneurs/countries/producers). The critical taxation level t c ≅ 1 − β Φ / 2 is presented by the horizontal dashed line.

Figure 6.

Same as Figure 5 but for Φ = 0.08 Rad .

When the simulation runs over many entrepreneurial parameter’s value (Φ), a phase diagram appears (Figure 7). The gray levels represent the mean value rafter 500 iterations. However, there are no gray levels, there are only black (no specialization and no trading) and white (full specialization and full trading). For low taxation level, the transition between the two ‘phases’ agrees with the theoretical line tc1βΦ/2.

Figure 7.

A two-dimensional phase diagram. The diagram represents r , which is a measure of market specialization, as a function of the entrepreneurial activity parameter Φ and the taxation level t. The darker the color, the lower is the value of r . The phase transition is clearly seen. The dashed line corresponds to t c ≅ 1 − β Φ / 2 .

It should be stressed that in this chapter, it was assumed that the entrepreneurial activity is bounded by regulations. These regulations were manifested by the uniform distribution. In case the regulations are less binding, and the entrepreneurial activity is unbounded and is affected only by human merits, then the distribution may be replaced by a normal, that is, Gaussian, distribution, in which case the transition between phases depends on the measurement time and is clearly less sharp.

6. Summary

In this chapter, a generalization of the Ricardian model was presented. Unlike the original model, the presented one takes into account:

  1. Entrepreneurial activities. The model regards the market as a perpetual process of entrepreneurial actions. The producers check random variations and choose the ones with the highest prospect of being profitable.

  2. Specialization. The model takes into account the fact that specialization is not a linear process.

  3. Taxes and tariffs. In the presence of taxes, the effective price that the buyer ‘sees’ is different from the one the seller ‘sees’. This fact is also taken into account.

The main result of this model is that when the entrepreneurial activity is bounded by regulations (and can be approximated by random variables with a uniform distribution), a critical taxation level appears, below which the market propagates toward full specialization, and the market clears by trading, while above this level, specialization is fully suppressed and no trading is possible. The transition between these two domains is extremely sharp and resembles a phase transition.

© 2018 The Author(s). Licensee IntechOpen. This chapter is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 3.0 License, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.

How to cite and reference

Link to this chapter Copy to clipboard

Cite this chapter Copy to clipboard

Er'el Granot (February 28th 2018). The Effect of Taxation, Specialization, and Entrepreneurial Activities on International Trading, Trade and Global Market, Vito Bobek, IntechOpen, DOI: 10.5772/intechopen.74751. Available from:

chapter statistics

180total chapter downloads

More statistics for editors and authors

Login to your personal dashboard for more detailed statistics on your publications.

Access personal reporting

Related Content

This Book

Next chapter

Location Choice of Inward FDIs in Korea: The Case of Japanese FDIs with Unexpected Shock in Home

By Seok-Joon Hwang and Xiaomin Li

Related Book

International Trade from Economic and Policy Perspective

Edited by Vito Bobek

First chapter

A Survey of Effects of International Trade on Growth

By Maria Hamideh Ramjerdi

We are IntechOpen, the world's leading publisher of Open Access books. Built by scientists, for scientists. Our readership spans scientists, professors, researchers, librarians, and students, as well as business professionals. We share our knowledge and peer-reveiwed research papers with libraries, scientific and engineering societies, and also work with corporate R&D departments and government entities.

More About Us