Open access

Nash Equilibrium Strategies in Fuzzy Games

Written By

Alireza Chakeri, Nasser Sadati and Guy A. Dumont

Submitted: 03 December 2011 Published: 27 March 2013

DOI: 10.5772/54677

From the Edited Volume

Game Theory Relaunched

Edited by Hardy Hanappi

Chapter metrics overview

4,149 Chapter Downloads

View Full Metrics

1. Introduction

Modern description of game theory is generally considered to have been started with the book "Theory of Games and Economic Behavior" [1]. Modern game theory has grown extremely well, in particular after the influential results of Nash [2-4]. It has been widely applied to many problems in economics, engineering, politics, etc.

A game is a model of a situation where two or more groups are in dispute over some issues [5]. The participants in a game are called the players. The possible actions available to players are referred to as strategies. When each player selects a strategy, it will determine an outcome to the game and the payoffs to all players, while tries to maximize his own payoff.

Classical game theory uses the extensive form and the strategic form to explain a game. The extensive form is represented by a game tree, in which the players make sequential actions. However, the strategic form is usually used to describe games with two decision makers, in which players' choices are made simultaneously. Unlike one-player decision making, where optimality has a clear sense, in multi person decision making the optimality is in the form of NE. An NE strategy is a strategy wherein, if a player knows his opponent’s strategy, he is totally satisfied and is unwilling to change his strategy.

In classical game theory it is assumed that all data of a game are known exactly by players. However, in real games, the players are often not able to evaluate exactly the game due to lack of information and precision in the available information of the situation. Harsanyi [6] treated imprecision in games with a probabilistic method and developed the theory of Bayesian games. This theory could not entirely solve the problem of imprecision in games, because it was limited to only one possible kind of imprecision. However, in reality, imprecision is of different types and can be modeled by fuzzy sets. The notion of fuzzy sets first appeared in the paper written by Zadeh [7]. This notion tries to show that to what degree an element belongs to a set. The degree, to which an element belongs to a set, is an element of the continuous interval [0, 1] rather than the Boolean values. Using the notion of fuzzy sets, each component in a game (set of players, set of strategies, set of payoffs, etc) can be fuzzified. Initially, fuzzy sets were used by Butnariu [8] in non-cooperative game theory. He used fuzzy sets to represent the belief of each player for strategies of other players. Since then, fuzzy set theory has been used in many non-cooperative [9-15] and cooperative games [16-17].

In this chapter, we will extend the NE set to fuzzy set in games with fuzzy numbers as payoffs. In this regard, using ranking fuzzy numbers, a fuzzy preference relation is constructed over payoffs and then the resultant priorities of payoffs are considered as the grades of being NE. Hence, if a player knows the opponent’s strategy, he is satisfied with his own strategy by the degree that this strategy has priority for him. The more priority the players feel for each strategy, the more possible the strategy becomes the game’s equilibrium. This generalization shows the distribution of Nash grades in the matrix form of the game. In other words, we can consider strategies with high grades of equilibrium which are not necessarily the equilibrium points. In the proposed approach, the effect of different viewpoints (optimism and pessimism) on the result of the game is also studied.

The remainder of this chapter is organized as follows. Section 2 reviews the backgrounds on fuzzy set theory. This section discusses the basic definition of fuzzy numbers, fuzzy extension principle and ranking fuzzy numbers. Section 3 briefly presents the fuzzy preference relation and a way to obtain priorities from fuzzy preference matrix. In this section, preference ordering of the alternatives and its transformation into fuzzy preference relation is also discussed. Section 4 introduces the proposed algorithm to find the Nash grades for pure and mixed strategies in the matrix form of the game. Two examples and their detailed results are presented in Section 5. Finally, Section 6 contains some concluding remarks.

Advertisement

2. Backgrounds on fuzzy set theory

There are two well-known frameworks for quantifying the lack of knowledge and precision, namely, probabilistic and possibilistic uncertainty type. The probabilistic framework deals with the uncertain events with a probability distribution function (PDF). However, there are some situations in which there is not much information about the PDF of uncertain parameters or they are inherently not repeatable. In possibilistic framework, for each uncertain eventM˜, a membership functionμM˜(x)is defined which describes how much each elementx, of universe of discourse U(the set of all values that xcan take) belongs toM˜. Different types of membership functions can be used to describe uncertain values. Fuzzy numbers have also been used in many decision making problems. The following definition of fuzzy numbers is most commonly used [18];

Definition 1: The fuzzy numberM˜is a convex normalized fuzzy set of the real lineRsuch that

  1. There is exactly onex0withμM˜(x0)=1.

  2. μM˜(x)
Mα={xR|M(x)α},α[0,1] is also called α-cut of M˜. From definition 1, α-cuts of a fuzzy numberM˜are closed real intervals, that is
Mα=[aα,bα]α[0,1]E1

2.1. Fuzzy extension principle

Fuzzy extension principle, which was introduced by Zadeh in [19], is an essential principle in fuzzy set theory to generalize the concepts and structures of classical mathematics to fuzzy mathematics as follows [20]

Definition 2: Let U1,,Unare UoDs and U=U1××Un be their Cartesian product. Also assume that M˜1,,M˜n are fuzzy subsets of U1,,Un, respectively. Moreover, let y=f(x1,,xn) be a mapping from UtoY. Now if B˜=f(M˜1,,M˜n), then the membership function of B˜is defined as follows

μB˜(y)=μf(M˜1,,M˜n)(y)={supx1,,xny=f(x1,,xn)min{μM˜1(x1),,μM˜n(xn)}f1(y)ϕ0f1(y)=ϕE2

Based on the above definition, one-dimensional operators and two-dimensional operators on fuzzy numbers can be represented by the following definitions, respectively.

Definition 3: Assume that M˜is a fuzzy number and f:RRis a one-dimensional operator. According to fuzzy extension principle, f(M˜) is a fuzzy set with the following membership function

μf(M˜)(y)={supx,y=f(x)μM˜(x)f1(y)ϕ0f1(y)=ϕE3

In definition 3, iff(x)=λx, then the scalar product of the real valueλinto fuzzy numberM˜ is a fuzzy number with the following membership function

μλM˜(x)=μM˜(xλ)E4

Definition 4: Assume that M˜and N˜are fuzzy numbers andf:R×RRis a two-dimensional operator. According to fuzzy extension principle, M˜N˜ is a fuzzy set with the following membership function

μM˜N˜(z)=supz=xymin(μM˜(x),μN˜(y))E5

As a special case, the result of the summation operator is also a fuzzy number as follows

μM˜+N˜(z)=supz=x+ymin(μM˜(x),μN˜(y))E6

2.2. Ranking fuzzy numbers

Ranking fuzzy numbers seems a necessary procedure in decision making when alternatives are fuzzy numbers. Various methods for ranking fuzzy subsets have been proposed. Yager in [21] introduced a function for ranking fuzzy subsets in unit interval which is based on the integral of mean of the α-cuts. Jain in [22], Baldwin and Guild in [23] were also suggested methods for ordering fuzzy subsets in the unit interval. Ibanez and Munoz in [24] have developed a subjective approach for ranking fuzzy numbers. In this chapter, we use the subjective approach, as introduced in [24].

Ibanez and Munoz in [24] defined the following number as the average index for M˜

VP(M˜)=YfM˜(α)dP(α)M˜UE7

whereYis a subset of the unit interval andPis a probability distribution onY.

The definition of fM˜could be subjective for decision maker. In [24] the following definition for fM˜has been suggested, in which the parameterλdetermines the optimism-pessimism degree of the decision maker

fM˜λ:YR,fM˜λ(α)=λbα+(1λ)aαE8

whereλ[0,1]and

Mα=[aα,bα]E9
.

When an optimistic decision maker (λ=1) wants to choose the greatest value, the upper extreme of the interval (bα) would be chosen, i.e. he prefers to choose the greatest possible value. A pessimism person (λ=0) on the opposite prefers to decide on the lower extreme of the interval (aα).

UsingVP()in (7), the ordering relations between fuzzy numbers A˜and B˜can be given as

A˜B˜VP(A˜)VP(B˜)A˜,B˜UE10

The fuzzy numberA˜is not preferred toB˜, if and only if their average index is the same

A˜B˜VP(A˜)=VP(B˜)A˜,B˜UE11

For convenience, let Y=[0,1] andPis the Lebesgue measure on [0, 1], as used in [24]. Then, the following VP(M˜)is derived for a specificλ

VP(M˜)=01(λbα+(1λ)aα)dαE12

As a special case, the average index for triangular fuzzy numbers can be given as follows

VLλ=bλ+(a12b)E13

where, a triangular fuzzy number with notation M˜=T(a,c,b)is used as shown in Figure 1.

Figure 1.

Triangular fuzzy number, M˜=T(a,c,b).

Advertisement

3. Preference relations

3.1. Fuzzy preference relations

Preference relation is one of the most regular tools for stating decision maker's preferences. In the process of making decision, individuals are asked to give their preferences over an alternative, which is based on their comparison according to one's desire. Various kinds of preference relations have been developed including multiplicative preference relation [25], fuzzy preference relation [26], linguistic preference relation [27] and intuitionistic preference relation [28].

For a decision making situation, let X={x1,x2,,xn} be a discrete set of alternatives. A preference relationPon the setXis defined by a functionμP=X×XD, whereDis the domain of representation of preference degrees provided by the decision maker for each pair of alternatives. In many situations, due to lack of information about the problems, the goals, constraints and consequences are not precisely known. Because of these uncertainties, fuzzy set theory allows a more flexible framework to express the preferences. Fuzzy preferences show the fuzziness of the decision maker's preferences. In [26], fuzzy preference relation is defined as follows.

Definition 5: A fuzzy preference relationRon the setXis defined as a matrix R=(rij)n×n with some properties given as

{rij+rji=1,rij0,rii=0.5, i,j=1,2,...,nE14

whererijdenotes the preference degree of the alternative xitoxj.

In particular,rij=0.5shows indifference between xiandxj. The case ofrij0.5indicates thatxiis preferred toxj. Asrijincreases, the degree of preference gets larger. Alsorij=1shows thatxiis absolutely preferred to xjand vice versa.

Deriving priorities, that is the degrees of importance of alternatives, are the main aspect of preference relations. Quite a number of approaches have been developed to derive priorities from fuzzy preference relations. Lipovetsky and Michael-Conklin [29] introduced an optimization approach and an eigen-problem to produce robust priority estimation of a fuzzy preference relation. Xu [30] developed a weighted least square approach and an eigenvector method for priorities of fuzzy preference relations. Xu and Da [31] proposed the Least Deviation method to obtain the priority vector of a fuzzy preference relation and considered its properties. In this chapter, we use the Least Deviation method presented in [31] to derive priorities from fuzzy preference relation. The algorithm to derive priorities in [31] is mentioned briefly as follows.

Let R=(rij)n×nbe a fuzzy preference relation and W=(w1,w2,,wn)be the priority vector which is going to be calculated such that wi shows the degree of priority of alternativexi, with the following properties

i=1nwi=1;wi0E15

Let k be the number of iterations:

Step 1. Initialize the weightW(0)=(w1,w2,,,wn), specify parameter 0ε1 and let k=0.

Step 2. Calculate the following term, whereh(rij)=9(2rij1)

μi(w(k))=j=1n[h(rij)(wj(k)wi(k))h(rji)(wi(k)wj(k))],iE16

If |μi(w(k))|εfor alli, then updatewbyw(k)and go to step 5, otherwise continue with step 3.

Step 3. |μm(w(k))|=maxi=1n{|μi(w(k))|}, calculate T(k)and thenxi(k)using

T(k)=(jmh(rmj)(wj(k)wm(k)))/(jmh(rjm)(wm(k)wj(k)))E17
xi(k)={T(k)wm(k)wi(k)E18

Step 4. Setk=k+1 and go to step 2.

Step 5. Obtainwas the priority vector.

Step 6. End.

3.2. Preference ordering of the alternatives

Individuals usually provide their preferences over the alternatives by preference ordering. Let's assume that an expert expresses his preferences onXby a preference orderingO={o(x1),o(x2),,o(xn)}. It is assumed that the lower the position of the alternative in the preference ordering, the more contentment for the individual. For instance, an expert states his preference ordering on X={x1,x2,x3} by the following ordering; o(x1)=2,o(x2)=1,o(x3)=3. This means that the alternative x2 is the best and alternative x3 is the worst.

3.3. Transforming preference ordering into fuzzy preference relation

An alternative satisfies the decision maker according to its position in the ordering preference relation. Various mappings to transform the ordering preference relation into fuzzy preference relation have been proposed [32-34]. In [32] a crisp relation was introduced for assessing the fuzzy preference relation, where the preference between alternativesxiandxjdepends only on the values of o(xi)ando(xj). In [33-34], the following relations was introduced to achieve fuzzy preference relation from an ordering preference

v(xi)=1o(xi)1n1E19
rij=12(1+v(xi)v(xj))E20

whererij denotes the preference between alternativesxiandxj.

Advertisement

4. Fuzzy games

In a strategic game, there arenplayers and nsistrategies for playeri. SupposeXiis the strategy set for playeri defined as follows

Xi={x1i,x2i,...,xnsii}E21

In pure strategy, letsi denotes the strategy chosen by playeriand si denotes the strategies chosen by the other players. Then Πi(s1,,si,,sn)=Πi(si,si)is the payoff achieved by playeri. By definition of classical game theory, (s1*,,sn*)is the pure strategy Nash equilibrium, if and only if [35]

Πi(s1*,,si*,,sn*)Πi(s1*,,si,,sn*)i{1,,n},siXiE22

In mixed strategy, each player assigns a probability distributionσi=(σ1i,,σnsii)Σiover his strategies, where Σidetermines all possible probability distributions for playeri. Then, the expected payoff for playeriis the real valueEi(σ1,,σn), whereEdenotes the expectation operator. In this regard, mixed strategy Nash equilibrium (σ1*,,σn*) is defined as follows

Ei(σ1*,,σi*,,σn*)Ei(σ1*,,σi,,σn*)i{1,,n},σiΣiE23

In real games, players must often make their decisions under unclear or fuzzy information. In this regard, there are several approaches for explaining games with fuzzy set theory. As discussed earlier, a game has three main components: a set of players, a set of strategies and a set of payoffs. The set of players is defined as fuzzy set when the concept of coalition in cooperative games is fuzzified. Butnariu in [17] proposed core and stable sets in fuzzy coalition games, and introduced a degree of participation for players in a coalition. Mares in [16] considered fuzzy core in fuzzy cooperative games, where possibility for each fuzzy coalition was considered as fuzzy interval, and an extension of the core in classic TU games. He discussed Shapely value in cooperative games with deterministic characteristics and fuzzy coalitions. In [9], the concept of fuzzy strategies has been introduced. It defines a strategy set consisting of fuzzy subspaces of strategy spaces and assigned a fuzzy payoff for each set of player's strategies. Hence, they have defined a fuzzy inference system (fuzzy If-Then rules). However, they have assumed some real values as strategies and have solved the games with common crisp methods. The first two steps seem rational for modeling any system according to its specifications, however the final step is not a reasonable fuzzy decision making approach to find NEs. Generally, since the final decision of a player is a number in real world problems, they can not adopt fuzzy strategies except when meaningful interpretations exist. However, we should remark that fuzzy strategies are constructive to model the games and calculate the payoffs.

Defining payoffs as fuzzy sets is reasonable in the following two main situations, and lead to fuzzy numbers as payoffs.

  1. When there is not sufficient information about the payoffs and they are not inherently repeatable.

  2. When calculation of payoffs is difficult or time-consuming. Hence, they are usually defined by fuzzy if-then rules.

In this chapter, we consider pure and mixed strategies in games with fuzzy numbers as payoffs. In this regard, in pure strategies,Πi(si,si)is considered as a fuzzy number. Also, in mixed strategies, the expected values are calculated based on the fuzzy extension principle and definitions 3 and 4, because the payoffs are fuzzy numbers.

Advertisement

4. Playing games with fuzzy numbers as payoffs

In classical game theory, a crisp payoff is either greater than or less than others. However, in fuzzy ones, there are uncertainties in comparing fuzzy payoffs. We model these uncertainties using fuzzy preference relation on the preference ordering of the expected values. In this regard, using ranking fuzzy numbers, a fuzzy preference relation reflecting the uncertainties in payoffs is constructed and then, the resultant priorities of payoffs are considered as the grades of being NE. This definition for the grade of being NE seems meaningful because if a player knows the opponent’s strategy, he is satisfied with his strategy by the degree that this strategy has priority for him. The more priority the players get for each strategy, the more possible the strategy is the game’s equilibrium. The proposed algorithm to find the grade of being NE for every mixed strategy is shown in Table 1.

1. i, do steps 2-9.
2. For playeri, determine the optimism-pessimism degreeλ.
3. σi, do steps 4-9.
4. Fix the opponent's mixed strategyσi.
5. σi, calculate the average index of the resultant expected value according to (11).
6. Order the expected values according to their average index in descending order, according to (9).
7. Transform the ordering preference relation into fuzzy preference relation according to (18-19).
8. Derive priorities of expected values from the resultant fuzzy preference relation based on the least deviation method.
9. For every mixed strategy(σi,σi), set its grade of being NE equal to its corresponding priorities.
10. For every mixed strategy(σi,σi), set its overall grade of being NE equal to the minimum of its grade of being NE for each player.

Table 1.

Algorithm to find the grade of being NE for each mixed strategy

Advertisement

5. Simulation results

5.1. Application in pure strategy

In this subsection, games with two players are considered because of their easier understanding. However, our algorithm can be implemented to more than two players. Consider a fuzzy game, as defined in Table 2. Player one and player two have three strategies, namely a1, a2, a3 and b1, b2, b3, respectively. Each cell includes two fuzzy triangular numbers as payoffs; the first for player one and the second for player two.

(Π1,Π2)b1b2b3
a1T(4,5,6),T(1,3,5)T(5,6,7),T(2,3,4)T(4,5,6),T(1.5,3,4.5)
a2T(2,3,4),T(0,1,2)T(1,3,5),T(3,4,5)T(2,3,4),T(1,3,5)
a3T(3,4,5),T(2,4,6)T(3,5,7),T(1,3,5)T(6,7,8),T(4,6,8)

Table 2.

A sample game with fuzzy payoffs

Implementing the algorithm presented in Table 1, there can be several grades of being NE for the game corresponding to differentλs. Tables 3 and 4 present the priority of each payoff according to possible choices ofλ.

b1b2b3
a1(0.7,0.08)(0.7,0.7)(0.22,0.22)
a2(0.08,0.08)(0.08,0.7)(0.08,0.22)
a3(0.22,0.22)(0.22,0.08)(0.7,0.7)

Table 3.

Priorities of payoffs for λ ≤ ¼

b1b2b3
a1(0.7,0.7)(0.7,0.08)(0.22,0.22)
a2(0.08,0.08)(0.08,0.7)(0.08,0.22)
a3(0.22,0.22)(0.22,0.08)(0.7,0.7)

Table 4.

Priorities of payoffs for λ > 1/4

The minimum priority of all payoffs in a cell is interpreted now as the grade of being Nash equilibrium of that cell. The results of the mentioned game is tabulated in Tables 5 and 6 for the possible choice ofλ, respectively

b1b2b3
a10.080.70.22
a20.080.080.08
a30.220.080.7

Table 5.

Grades of being NE for λ ≤ ¼

b1b2b3
a10.70.080.22
a20.080.080.08
a30.220.080.7

Table 6.

Grades of being NE for λ > 1/4

The difference between the results of Tables 5 and 6 is meaningful. As the player 2 becomes optimistic, he prefers to choose the greatest possible outcome. Hence, between three alternatives{T(3,2),T(3,1),T(3,1.5)}, T(3,2)has the most priority. But a pessimistic player prefers to choose alternativeT(3,1).

5.2. Application in mixed strategy

In this subsection, mixed strategies in bi-matrix games are considered. Consider a fuzzy bi-matrix game as defined in Table 7.

(Π1,Π2)b1b2
a1T(10,11,12),T(3,4,5)T(3,4,5),T(0.5,2,3.5)
a2T(2,4,6),T(0,1,2)T(6,7,8),T(2,4,6)

Table 6.

A sample game with fuzzy payoffs

Using the proposed approach, every mixed strategy has a grade of being NE as shown in Figures 2 and 3 for each neutral player (λ=0.5).

Figure 2.

Grades of being NE for Player 1

Figure 3.

Grades of being NE for Player 2

Now, the minimum priorities for players can be interpreted as the overall grades of being NE. We remark that the minimum operator can be replaced by any other T-norms. The results of the game presented in Table 7, is shown in Figure 4.

Figure 4.

Grades of being NE for neutral players

Grade of being NE is high around two pure strategies, that is (p1=(0,1),p2=(0,1))and(p1=(1,0),p2=(1,0)). The mixed strategy (p1=(0.7,0.3),p2=(0.3,0.7)) has also high grade of being NE.

In addition, the effect of optimism-pessimism degree of players in distribution of Nash grades is studied. For instance, if two players are optimistic (λ=1), the Nash grades are the same as Figure 5. If two players are pessimistic (λ=0), the Nash grades are the same as Figure 6.

The difference between the results of Figures 4 and 5 is important. As the player becomes optimistic, he prefers to choose the greatest possible outcome. Hence, payoff T(4,1.5)gets more priority than payoff T(4,1). In addition, Nash grades for neutral players are approximately the combination of Nash grades for optimistic and pessimistic players.

Figure 5.

Grades of being NE for optimistic players

Figure 6.

Grades of being NE for pessimistic players

Advertisement

6. Conclusion

In this chapter, some concepts in fuzzy sets including fuzzy numbers, fuzzy extension principle, ranking of fuzzy numbers and fuzzy preference relations were briefly introduced and consequently used to develop a new approach for practically analyzing the games with fuzzy numbers as payoffs. In this regard, a fuzzy preference relation was constructed on the preference ordering of payoffs using ranking fuzzy numbers. The priority of each payoff then was derived using the least deviation method. The priorities of payoffs were interpreted as the grades of being NE. We should remark that, in this chapter, we were not looking to show the pure and mixed strategy NEs, but rather we tried to assign a graded membership to each strategy to determine how much it is NE, i.e. it has the possibility for being NE.

References

  1. 1. Von NeumannJMorgensternO1944Theory of Games and Economic Behavior.New York: Wiley.
  2. 2. NashJ1950Equilibrium Points in n-Person Games. Proc. Nat. Academy Sci. 364849
  3. 3. NashJ1950The Bargaining Problem. Econometrica. 18155162
  4. 4. NashJ1951Non-Cooperative Games.Ann. Math. 54286295
  5. 5. FraserN. MHipelK. W1984Conflict Analysis: Models and Resolutions.New York: North-Holland.
  6. 6. HarsanyiJ. C1967Games with Incomplete Information Played by "Bayesian" Players, i-iii. Management Science. 14159182
  7. 7. Zadeh L. A (1965) Fuzzy Sets. Inform. Contr. 8 338353 .
  8. 8. ButnariuD1978Fuzzy Games: A Description of the ConceptFuzzy Sets and Systems1181192
  9. 9. GaragicDCruzJ. B2003an Approach to Fuzzy Non-Cooperative Nash Games. J. Optim. Theory Appl. 118475491
  10. 10. SongQKandelA1999A Fuzzy Approach to Strategic GamesIEEE Trans. Fuzzy Syst. 7634642
  11. 11. VijayVChandraSBectorC. R2005Matrix Games with Fuzzy Goals and Fuzzy PayoffsOmega33425429
  12. 12. MaedaT2003On Characterization of Equilibrium Strategy of Two-Person Zero-Sum Games with Fuzzy PayoffsFuzzy Sets and Systems139283296
  13. 13. NishizakiISakawaM2000Equilibrium Solutions in Multiobjective Bimatrix Games with Fuzzy Payoffs and Fuzzy GoalsFuzzy Sets and Systems11199116
  14. 14. KimW. KLeebK. H2001Generalized Fuzzy Games and Fuzzy Equilibria. Fuzzy Sets and Systems. 122293301
  15. 15. LiK. WKarrayFHipelK. WKilgourD. M2001Fuzzy Approach to the Game of Chicken.IEEE Trans on Fuzzy Syst. 9608623
  16. 16. Mares M (2001) Fuzzy Cooperative Games. Heidelberg: Physica-Verlag.
  17. 17. ButnariuD1979Solution Concepts for n-Person Fuzzy Games. Advances in Fuzzy Set Theory and Applications. 339354
  18. 18. ZimmermannH. J1996Fuzzy Set Theory and its Applications.Kluwer Academic Publishers.
  19. 19. ZadehL. A1975The Concept of Linguistic Variable and Its Application to Approximate Reasoning.Inform. Sci. 8199249
  20. 20. YagerR. R1986A Characterization of the Extension PrincipleFuzzy Sets and Systems. 18205217
  21. 21. YagerR. R1981A Procedure for Ordering Fuzzy Subsets of the Unit IntervalInform. Sci. 24143161
  22. 22. JainR1977A Procedure for Multiple Aspect Decision Making Using Fuzzy SetsInt. J. Systems Sci. 817
  23. 23. BaldwinJ. FGuildN. C. F1979Comparison of Fuzzy Sets on the Same Decision SpaceFuzzy Sets and Systems2213231
  24. 24. IbanezL. M. CMunozA. G1989A Subjective Approach for Ranking Fuzzy NumbersFuzzy Sets and Systems29145153
  25. 25. SaatyT. L1980The Analytic Hierarchy Process. New York: McGraw-Hill.
  26. 26. S. AOrlovsky1978Decision-Making with a Fuzzy Preference RelationFuzzy Sets and Systems1155167
  27. 27. HerreraFHerrera-viedmaEVerdegayJ. L1995A Sequential Selection Process in Group Decision Making with Linguistic Assessment. Information Science. 223239
  28. 28. AtanassovK1986Intuitionistic Fuzzy Sets. Fuzzy Sets and Systems. 8796
  29. 29. LipovetskySMichael Conklin W (2002Robust Estimation of Priorities in the AHPEuropean Journal of Operational Research137110122
  30. 30. XuZ2002Two Methods for Priorities of Complementary Judgment Matrices_Weighted Least-Square Method and Eigenvector Method. Systems Engineering-Theory & Practice. 227175
  31. 31. XuZDaQ2005A Least Deviation Method to Obtain the Priority Vector of a Fuzzy Preference Relation. European Journal of operational Research164206216
  32. 32. ChiclanaFHerreraFHerrera-viedmaEPoyatosM. C1996A Classification Method of Alternatives for Multiple Preference Ordering Criteria Based on Fuzzy Majority.Journal of Fuzzy Mathematics.
  33. 33. DombiJ1995A General Framework for the Utility-Based and Outranking Methods. Fuzzy Logic and Soft Computing. 202208
  34. 34. TaninoT1988Fuzzy Preference Relations in Group Decision Making. Non-Conventional Preference Relations in decision making. Springer. 5471
  35. 35. FudenbergDTiroleJ1991Game TheoryMIT Press, Cambridge, MA.

Written By

Alireza Chakeri, Nasser Sadati and Guy A. Dumont

Submitted: 03 December 2011 Published: 27 March 2013