Open access peer-reviewed chapter

Multi-Criteria Decision-Making in the Implementation of Renewable Energy Sources

Written By

Dejan Jovanovic and Ivan Pribicevic

Submitted: 22 October 2016 Reviewed: 06 February 2017 Published: 07 June 2017

DOI: 10.5772/67734

From the Edited Volume

Computer Simulation

Edited by Dragan Cvetkovic

Chapter metrics overview

1,644 Chapter Downloads

View Full Metrics

Abstract

The consideration of renewable energy sources as sources for the production of electricity, demands an approach that would enable an analysis which comprehends various factors and stakeholders. The Preference Ranking Organization METHod for Enrichment Evaluations (PROMETHEE), as a mathematical model for multi-criteria decision-making, is one of the ideal methods used when it is necessary to rank scenarios according to specific criteria, depending on whom the ranking is applied. This chapter presents various scenarios whose ranking is done according to defined criteria and weight coefficients for each of the stakeholders. This model recognized and accepted according to the theory of decision-making could be used as a tool for so-called stakeholder value approach.

Keywords

  • renewable energy sources
  • PROMETHEE
  • the production of electricity
  • stakeholder value
  • multi-criteria decision-making proces
  • National Renewable Energy Action Plan (NAPOIE)
  • mini hydros
  • biomass
  • wind
  • solar
  • geothermal energy

1. Introduction

The basis for this chapter was document which established the goals in usage of renewable energy sources until 2020 (National Renewable Energy Action Plan of the Republic of Serbia further on NAPOIE) [2], as well as the manner in which they are to be achieved. In addition, it has the goal to enhance investments in the field of renewable energy sources.

‘According to article 20 of the Treaty Establishing Energy Community (further on: UOEnZ), the Republic of Serbia accepted the obligation to apply European Directives in the field of renewable energy sources (further on: OIE) —Directive 2001/77/EC on the promotion of the use of energy from renewable sources and Directive 2003/30/EC on the promotion of the use of biofuels and other renewable fuels for transport. Those Directives were gradually replaced since 2009, and in January 2012 abolished by the new Directive 2009/28/EC of the European Parliament and the Council of the 23rd of April 2009 on the promotion of the use of energy from renewable sources, amending and subsequently repealing Directives 2001/77/EC and 2003/30/EC CELEX No. 32009L0028’.1**

With the adoption of the ‘Law of Ratification…’,2 [3] the Republic of Serbia internationally committed to create NAPOIE [2].

Data given in Tables 1 and 2 were used as input data for this chapter.

Type of renewable energy sources(MW)Estimated work hours (h)(GWh)(ktoe)Participation (%)
HE (over 10 MW)250443011089530.3
MHE (up to 10 MW)18831505925116.2
Wind energy500200010008627.4
Solar energy1013001310.4
Biomass: power plants with combined production10064006405517.5
Biogas (manure): power plants with combined production307500225196.2
Geothermal energy17000710.2
Waste360001820.5
Landfill gas1050005041.4
Total planned capacity10923653314100.0

Table 1.

The production of electricity from renewable energy sources from new plants in 20201.

1 Full name “Law on Ratification of the Treaty Establishing Energy Community between the European Community and the Republic of Albania, Republic of Bulgaria, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Republic of Croatia, Former Yugoslav Republic of Macedonia, Republic of Montenegro, Romania, Republic of Serbia and United Nations Interim Administration Mission on Kosovo in compliance with the Resolution 1244 of the UN Security Council” („Službeni glasnik RS”, no. 62/06 [2].

Type of renewable energy sources(MW)(GWh)Specific investment costs* (€/kW)Price according to planned installed capacity until 2020 (millions €)
HE (over 10 MW)25011081819454.8
MHE (up to 10 MW)1885922795525.5
Plants powered by wind energy50010001417708.5
Plants powered by solar energy1013250025.0
Biomass: power plants with combined production1006404522452.2
Biogas (manure): power plants with combined production302254006120.2
Geothermal energy1741154.1
Waste318414712.4
Landfill gas1050200020.0
Total planned capacity109236532322.6

Table 2.

Estimated finances for each of the technologies using renewable energy sources in the production of electricity needed to complete the planned share in energy production from new capacities until 2020 in electric energy sector1.

1 Full name “Law on Ratification of the Treaty Establishing Energy Community between the European Community and the Republic of Albania, Republic of Bulgaria, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Republic of Croatia, Former Yugoslav Republic of Macedonia, Republic of Montenegro, Romania, Republic of Serbia and United Nations Interim Administration Mission on Kosovo in compliance with the Resolution 1244 of the UN Security Council” („Službeni glasnik RS”, no. 62/06 [2].

Types of renewable energy sources taken in consideration in this chapter are as follows:

  • Mini hydros (up to 10 MW).

  • Wind energy.

  • Solar energy.

  • Biomass.

  • Geothermal energy.

The National Renewable Energy Action Plan of the Republic of Serbia (NAPOIE) defined target values, that is, the amount of GWh expected to be produced from every renewable energy source and to be delivered in the system. The defined goal is 2252 GWh obtained from following renewable energy sources: mini hydros, biomass, solar, wind and geothermal energy (Table 3).

Renewable energy typeMtoe
Hydro0.80
Solar0.60
Biomass2.25
Wind0.20
Geothermal energy0.20

Table 3.

Available potentials [4].

The goal is to verify the ranking sequence of renewable energy sources if only one of the listed renewable energy sources would be delivering the total expected amount of GWh into the system and to rank scenarios according to stakeholders3, on the basis of previously defined criteria and calculated weight coefficients, and also to establish whether the sequence of renewable energy sources is identical for all stakeholders.

On the basis of ranking achieved this way, we may determine which type of renewable energy source is the priority, depending on the stakeholder, and also whether the participation of all listed types is justified.

A multi-criteria analysis will provide a clearly established sequence of renewable energy sources for the stakeholders, and according to clearly established criteria. This sequence is important for the establishing of priorities.

For solving this type of problems, one of the mathematical models that can be used is the one developed by Jean-Pierre Brans in 1982, for a multi-criteria decision-making in a group of alternatives described with several attributes.

Advertisement

2. Theoretical overview of the PROMETHEE

The Preference Ranking Organization METHod for Enrichment Evaluations (PROMETHEE)4 is part of a group of methods for multi-criteria decision-making within a group of alternatives described with several attributes, used as criteria. This method enables a comprehensive structuring of quality and quantity criteria of different importance into a relation of partial organization in a unique result (PROMETHEE II), on the basis of which alternatives can be ranked in an absolute manner.

We will consider a multi-criteria problem:

Max{(k1(a),,kk(a))|aA},E1

where A is a finite group of activities and ki = 1,…, k are usefulness criteria which should be maximized or fulfilled according to the principle ‘bigger is better’ (this supposition enables a more simple presentation of the method—in cases when some of the criteria are price criteria, they can be transformed into usefulness criteria, or we can adjust the proceeding to those criteria as well).

The application of the PROMETHEE is characterized by two steps:

  1. constructing a preference relation within a group of alternatives A,

  2. using this relation to find an answer to the problem (1.1).

In the first step, a complex preference relation is formed (in order to stress the fact that this relation is based on the consideration of more criteria, this relation is called outranking relation), based on the generalization of the notion of the criteria. A preference index is then defined and a complex preference relation is obtained, which is shown in a graph representation. The essence of this step is that the decision maker (stakeholder) must express his preference between two alternatives (action and activity), according to every criterion, on the basis of the difference (differentiation) of criteria values of alternatives which are being compared.

PROMETHEE II can be a tool for ‘Management philosophy that regards maximization of the interests of its all stakeholders (customers, employees, shareholders and the community) as its highest objective’.5

The preference relation obtained this way is used so that input and output flows are calculated for each alternative, in graphs or tables. On the basis of these flows, the decision maker can apply partial ranking (PROMETHEE I) or absolute ranking (PROMETHEE II) in the group of alternatives.

In this chapter, the absolute ranking method PROMETHEE II was used.

2.1. PROMETHEE preference relation

Let k be a real function used to express one of the attributes used as a criterion for comparing alternatives:

k:ARE2

Let us assume that this is a usefulness criterion, that is, that alternatives (scenarios/models) are compared according to this criterion on the basis of the principle ‘bigger is better’.

For every alternative a dA, k(a) a criterion value is calculated according to criterion k. When two alternatives a, b dA are being compared, the result of that comparison is expressed as a preference.

With preference function P

P:A×A[0,1]E3

the intensity of preference for alternative a in relation to alternative b is expressed, with the following interpretation:

  • P (a, b) = 0 marks indifference between a and b, that is, there is no preference of a over b,

  • P (a, b) 0 marks weak preference of a over b,

  • P (a, b) 1 marks strong preference of a over b,

  • P (a, b) = 1 marks strict preference of a over b.

Preference function that is added to a given criterion is the difference function of criteria value of alternatives, and it can be written as

P(a,b)=P(k(a)k(b))=P(d)E4

P(d) is a non-decreasing function that assumes value zero for negative difference values d = k (a) − k (b), if the functions should be maximized, that is, P (a, b) = P (k (a) − k (b)), that is, d = −(k (a) − k (b)) if the criterion is minimized (Table 4).

Table 4.

Types of functions in the application of the PROMETHEE1.

1Taken from Ref. [5].

2.2. Multi-criteria preference index

Let us assume that the decision maker sets preference function Pi and weight ti; for every criterion ki (i = 1, …,n) of the problem (2.2).

Weight ti is the measure of relative importance of the criterion ki. If all criteria have the same value for the decision maker, all weights are equal.

Multi-criteria preference index IP is defined as the medium of preference functions Pi:

IP(a,b)=i=1ktiPi(a,b)i=1ktiE5

IP (a,b) represents intensity, that is, the strength of decision maker’s preference for activity a over activity b, when all criteria are compared at the same time. It varies between values 0 and 1.

  • P (a, b) 0 marks weak preference of a over b for all criteria,

  • P (a, b) 1 marks strong preference of a over b for all criteria.

This can also be shown in a graph. Between two nodes (two activities) a and b there are two arches with values IP(a, b) and IP(b, a). This relation is shown in Figure 1. There is no direct connection between IP(a, b) and IP(b, a).

Figure 1.

IP relation. Taken from Ref. [5].

Output and input flow:

Input and output flows can be defined for every node (shown in Figure 2.)

Figure 2.

Output flow. Taken from Ref. [5].

  1. Output flow is the sum of values of output flows:

    T+(a)=xkIP(a,x)

  2. Input flow is the sum of values of input flows (Figure 3):

    T(a)=xkIP(a,x)

Figure 3.

Input flow. Ibid 11, Ref. [5].

Advertisement

3. Absolute ranking: PROMETHEE II

If the decision maker wants an absolute ranking, the clear flow is considered:

Absolute ranking (PII, III) is defined in the following manner:

  • a PII b (a prefers b) if T(a) > T(b).

  • a III b (a is indifferent to b) if T(a) = T(b).

Elements of scientific research6 are all the elements that have to be defined so that the aforementioned mathematical model could be applied. Those comprehend:

  • stakeholders

  • criteria

  • weight coefficients

  • preference functions (for every criterion)

  • suggested models.

Stakeholders considered in ranking are as follows:

  • State (DR)

  • Potential investors (PI)

  • Local community (LZ).

3.1. Criteria

PRMOTHEE needs criteria to be defined, according to whom the ranking will be done. Criteria used in this study are presented in Table 5.

K1Maximal usage of available potentials
K2Price according to planned installed capacity
K3Incentive purchase price
K4Technology development
K5Supply safeness, expected work hours
K6Possibility of combined production of electric and thermal energy
K7Contribution to local development and welfare
K8Social acceptability and sustainability of other influences on the environment
K9Period of investment return
K10Installed power

Table 5.

Criteria for ranking scenarios.

These 10 criteria can be divided into two categories:

  1. Empirical criteria, based on the data taken from NAPOIE (K1, K2, K3, K5, K9 and K10).

  2. Description criteria (K4, K6, K7 and K8).

Weight coefficients are calculated and given in Table 4.

Since each of the stakeholders treats each of those 10 criteria in a different manner, it is essential to define weight coefficients so that every criterion has a weight definition in relation to the stakeholder. For each of the stakeholders, the criteria were sorted into three categories:

  • Very important,

  • Important,

  • Of little importance.

An assessment of weight coefficients was made on that basis, with values for K attributed on the scale of 1–10, starting from the categorization of the criteria. A representation of weight coefficients is given in Table 6.

Weight coefficient titi
State
k1; k5; k10(8 + 9 + 10)/3 = 90.1636Very important: 16.36%
k2; k3; k6; k7; k8(3 + 4 + 5 + 6 + 7)/5 = 50.0909Important: 9.09%
k4; k9(1 + 2)/2 = 1.50.02727Of little importance: 2.72%
Investors
k2; k3; k4; k9(7 + 8 + 9 + 10)/4 = 8.50.154545Very important: 15.45%
k5; k6; k10(4 + 5 + 6)/3 = 50.0909Important: 9.09%
k1; k7; k8(1 + 2 + 3)/3 = 20.03636Of little importance: 3.63%
Local community
k6; k7; k8(8 + 9 + 10)/3 = 90.1636Very important: 16.36%
k1; k5(6 + 7)/2 = 6.50.11818Important: 11.818%
k2; k3; k4; K9; K10(1 + 2 + 3 + 4 + 5)/5 = 30.0545Of little importance: 5.45%

Table 6.

Calculation of weight coefficients.

Preference functions. A preference function is attributed to every defined criterion. Common functions according the PROMETHEE are presented in Table 4. For this chapter, the following allocation was adopted:

  • Type 1. A common function is attributed to K6. Type 1 function is used when there are only two expected results, and it provides an obvious preference. Because of that it is attributed to criterion K6, since the combined production of electric and thermal energy is either possible or impossible.

  • Type 3. A growing linear preference function is attributed to K2, K3, K5, K9 and K10. Type 3 function is used when the difference can be a constant value. The maximum value of difference is taken as decision threshold (m = dmax)

  • Type 4. A function with preference levels is attributed to K1, K4, K7 and K8. Type 4 function is used for discrete value differences and their outputs are discrete preferences 0, ½, 1 (m and n are decision thresholds). For criterion K1, assumed decision thresholds are m = 10% dmax, and n = 30% dmax, while for criteria K4, K7, K8 m = 1 and n = 2.

3.2. Suggested models

The following models (scenarios) were defined (Table 6):

  • The first model (A1) represents allocation A1. This allocation fits the goals planned until 2020 according to NAPOIE.

  • The second model (A2) represents allocation A2, in which the needed energy from renewable energy sources would be produced in mini hydros.

  • The third model (A3) represents allocation A3, in which the needed energy from renewable energy sources would be produced from biomass.

  • The fourth model (A4) represents allocation A4, in which the needed energy from renewable energy sources would be produced by the Sun.

  • The fifth model (A5) represents allocation A5, in which the needed energy from renewable energy sources would be produced by the wind.

  • The sixth model (A6) represents allocation A6, in which the needed energy from renewable energy sources would be produced from geothermal potentials.

N.B.: It is VERY important to point out here that, according to available potentials, as shown in Table 7 (data taken from the document ‘Politika Republike Srbije u oblasti OIE’), each of the renewable energy sources listed (mini hydros, biomass, solar, wind and geothermal energy) can deliver 2252 GWh of energy independently (Table 8 presents coneversion of available resources presented in Table 7 from Mtoe to GWh), which represents the remainder from the total of 3360 GWh, diminished by the amount delivered by hydro potentials >10 MW. The first model A1 of this chapter was given illustratively as the goal which was set to be reached and will be used in further researches as a continuation of this chapter.

A1A2A3A4A5A6
GWhGWhGWhGWhGWhGWh
Hydro potential
>10 MW110811081108110811081108
<10 MW59222520000
Biomass64002252000
Solar1300225200
Wind100000022520
Geothermal700002252
Total3360

Table 7.

Scenarios A1–A6.

Type of renewable energy sourcesMtoeGWh
Hydro0.89304
Biomass2.2526,167
Solar0.66978
Wind0.22326
Geothermal energy0.22326

Table 8.

Available potentials of renewable energy sources.

Scenaria are treated according to the defined criteria. Values of criteria for each scenaria are calculated and presetned in Table 9.

K1 (%)K2 (€)K3K4K5K6K7K8K9K10
A1PLAN43.001,356,627,9689.87435641346.1799
A2Hydro potential <10 MW24.201,998,203,1759.89531500249.0715
A3Biomass8.611,591,178,75010.74464001446.6352
A4Solar32.274,330,769,23118.453130001310.41732
A5Wind96.821,595,542,0009.20420000137.71126
A6Geothermal96.821,323,854,2868.30470001257.1322

Table 9.

Scenarios according to K criteria values.

Advertisement

4. Mathematical model

Criterion K4: Technology development
Technologies in laboratory and research phases (laboratory)1
Technologies in pilot programs (pilot)2
Technologies demanding further improvements to enhance their efficiency (further improvement)3
Commercially ready technologies with a reliable place in the overall local market (com_loc)4
Commercially ready technologies with a reliable place in the supranational and European market (com_EU)5

Criterion K7: Contribution to local development
Without any influence on local economy (none)1
Weak influence on local economy(weak)2
Moderate influence on local economy (only a small number of permanent workplaces) (moderate)3
Moderate to large influence on local economy (opening new workplaces and chains of companies in energy production sector)4
Very large influence on local economy (strong incentive to local growth, creation of small industrial regions on wider areas)5

Criterion K8: social acceptability and sustainability of other influences on the environment
Most inhabitants are against any installations, regardless of their surroundings (no)1
Inhabitants’ opinion is split (split)2
Most inhabitants accept installations, since they are far from inhabited areas and have no visible damaging effects (vis-res)3
Most inhabitants accept installations, since they are far from inhabited areas, regardless of whether there is a visual contact (res)4
Most inhabitants are pro installations (OK)5

Mathematical model representation for the state as a stakeholder

StateMinMinMinMaxMaxMaxMaxMaxMinMax
K1%K2 €K3K4K5K6K7K8K9K10
A2Hydro potential <10 MW0.24201,998,203,1759.89531500249.0715
A3Biomass0.08611,591,178,75010.74464001446.6352
A4Solar0.32274,330,769,23118.453130001310.41732
A5Wind0.96821,595,542,0009.20420000137.71126
A6Geothermal0.96821,323,854,2868.30470001257.1322

d(a2,ai)Hydro potential <10 MWDifferentiation d: difference between scenario a2 and other suggested scenarios
0.000000.00000000.00
Biomass−0.1559−407,024,4250.851−3250−1−20−2.4363
Solar0.0807233,266,0568.56218500111.4−1017
Wind0.7262−402,661,175−0.6911150011−1.3−411
Geothermal0.7262−674,348,889−1.601−3850−10−1−1.9393

P(a2,ai)Hydro potential <10 MWPreference function P: scenario a2 versus other suggested scenarios
0000000000
a3Biomass000.0992990.5000000.923
a4Solar0111100.50.510
a5Wind1000.50.6200.50.500
a6Geothermal1000.5000001
Ti0.16360.09090.09090.027270.16360.09090.09090.09090.027270.1636

d(a3,ai)Hydro potential <10 MWDifferentiation d: difference between scenario a3 and other suggested scenarios
0.1559407,024,425−0.85−132501202.4−363
Biomass0.000000.00000000.00
Solar0.23662,739,590,4817.71151001313.8−1380
Wind0.88214,363,250−1.54044001311.1−774
Geothermal0.8821−267,324,464−2.450−60002−10.530

P(a3,ai)Hydro potential <10 MWPreference function P: scenario a3 versus other suggested scenarios
0.50.148000.6371100.630
a3Biomass0000000000
a4Solar0.5110.51110.510
a5Wind10.0016000.862110.50.2890
a6Geothermal100000100.1311
ti0.16360.09090.09090.027270.16360.09090.09090.09090.027270.1636

d(a4,ai)Hydro potential<10 MWDifferentiation d: difference between scenario a4 and other suggested scenarios
−0.0807−2,332,566,056−8.56−2−18500−1−1−1.41017
Biomass−0.2366−2,739,590,481−7.71−1−5100−1−3−1−3.81380
Solar0.000000.00000000.00
Wind0.6455−2,735,227,231−9.25−1−700000−2.7606
Geothermal0.6455−3,006,914,945−10.16−1−5700−1−1−2−3.31410

P(a4,ai)Hydro potential <10 MWPreference function P: scenario a4 versus other suggested scenarios
0000000000.721
a3Biomass0000000000.978
a4Solar0000000000
a5Wind1000000000.43
a6Geothermal1t000000001
ti0.16360.09090.09090.027270.16360.09090.09090.09090.027270.1636

d(a5,ai)Hydro potential <10 MWDifferentiation d: difference between scenario a5 and other suggested scenarios
−0.7262402,661,1750.69−1−11500−1−11.3411
Biomass−0.8821−4,363,2501.540−4400−1−3−1−1.1774
Solar−0.64552,735,227,2319.2517000002.7−606
Wind0.000000.00000000.00
Geothermal0.0000−271,687,714−0.900−5000−1−1−2−0.6804

P(a3,ai)Hydro potential <10 MWPreference function P – scenario a5 versus other suggested scenarios
00.1470.075000000.4810.51
a3Biomass000.1660000000.962
a4Solar0110.5100010
a5Wind0000000000
a6Geothermal0000000001
ti0.16360.09090.09090.027270.16360.09090.09090.09090.027270.1636

d(a6,ai)Hydro potential <10 MWDifferentiation d – difference between scenario a6 and other suggested scenarios
−0.7262674,348,8891.60−138501011.9−393
Biomass−0.8821267,324,4642.4506000−21−0.5−30
Solar−0.64553,006,914,94510.16157001123.3−1410
Wind0.0000271,687,7140.90050001120.6−804
Geothermal0.000000.00000000.00

P(a6,ai)Hydro potential <10 MWPreference function P – scenario a6 versus other suggested scenarios
00.2240.15700.675100.50.5760
a3Biomass00.0890.24100.105000.500
a4Solar0110.5110.5110
a5Wind00.090.08800.87710.510.1820
a6Geothermal0000000000
ti0.16360.09090.09090.027270.16360.09090.09090.09090.027270.1636

IP(a2,a3)IP(a2,a4)IP(a2,a5)IP(a2,a6)
0.17360.490840.3695670.340835
IP(a3,a2)IP(a3,a4)IP(a3,a5)IP(a3,a6)
0.3984470.6953550.53990.421672
IP(a4,a2)IP(a4,a3)IP(a4,a5)IP(a4,a6)
0.1179560.1600010.2339480.3272
IP(a5, a2)IP(a5,a3)IP(a5,a4)IP(a5,a6)
0.1167330.1724730.3863050.1636
IP(a6,a2)IP(a6,a3)IP(a6,a4)IP(a6,a5)
0.297120.926250.6135550.391871

N.B.: IP = (ai,as), i,s = 2,3,4,5,6; IP = ∑tjPj(ai,as).

a2a3a4a5a6T+T
a200.17360.490840.3695670.3408350.3437110.111147
a30.39844700.6953550.53990.4216720.5138440.364169
a40.1179560.16000100.2339480.32720.209776−0.33674
a50.1167330.1724730.38630500.16360.209778−0.17404
a60.297120.0926250.6135550.39187100.3487930.035466
T−0.2325640.1496750.5465140.3838220.313327

The results for State are shown in Figure 4.

Figure 4.

Chart representation of ranking results for the state as a stakeholder.

The same approach could be usd for detailed calculation for the investors and local community as stakeholders.

For the investors as stakeholders:

Determination of preference index
IP(a2,a3)IP(a2,a4)IP(a2,a5)IP(a2,a6)
0.16110.5908950.2729980.359078
IP(a3,a2)IP(a3,a4)IP(a3,a5)IP(a3,a6)
0.3771970.6408830.4022090.33841
IP(a4,a2)IP(a4,a3)IP(a4,a5)IP(a4,a6)
0.1957460.2061780.216150.281805
IP(a5,a2)IP(a5,a3)IP(a5,a4)IP(a5,a6)
0.1434130.0874460.4772630.245445
IP(a6,a2)IP(a6,a3)IP(a6,a4)IP(a6,a5)
0.2940740.0414790.6227030.267196

N.B.: IP = (ai, as), i, s = 2,3,4,5,6; IP= ∑tjPj(ai,as).

a2a3a4a5a6T+T
a200.16110.5908950.2729980.3590780.3460180.09341
a30.37719700.6408830.4022090.338410.4396750.315624
a40.1957460.20617800.216150.2818050.22497−0.35797
a50.1434130.0874460.47726300.2454450.238392−0.05125
a60.2940740.0414790.6227030.26719600.3063630.000179
T-0.25260750.1240510.5829360.2896380.306185

The reuslts for investors are shown in Figure 5.

Figure 5.

Chart representation of ranking results for the investors as stakeholders.

For the local community as a stakeholder:

Determination of preference index
IP(a2,a3)IP(a2,a4)IP(a2,a5)IP(a2,a6)
0.0829110.3934180.3163570.19993
IP(a3,a2)IP(a3,a4)IP(a3,a5)IP(a3,a6)
0.4362190.6706580.5532050.34342
IP(a4,a2)IP(a4,a3)IP(a4,a5)IP(a4,a6)
0.0392950.0533010.1416150.17268
IP(a5,a2)IP(a5,a3)IP(a5,a4)IP(a5,a6)
0.0661090.0614760.2025680.0545
IP(a6,a2)IP(a6,a3)IP(a6,a4)IP(a6,a5)
0.3055340.101030.6115680.438984

IP = (ai, as), i,s = 2,3,4,5,6; IP= ∑tjPj(ai, as).

a2a3a4a5a6T+T
a200.0829110.3934180.3163570.199930.2481540.036365
a30.43621900.6706580.5532050.343420.5008760.426196
a40.0392950.05330100.1416150.172680.101723−0.36783
a50.0661090.0614760.20256800.05450.096163−0.26638
a60.3055340.101030.6115680.43898400.3642790.171647
T−0.2117890.07467950.4695530.362540.192633

The results for community are shown in Figure 6.

Figure 6.

Chart representation of ranking results for the local community as a stakeholder.

Advertisement

5. Chart representation of results

After applying the PROMETHEE, as a tool for stakeholder value approach, and after the ranking, we can reach following conclusions on the basis of results obtained:

The results obtained and shown in the charts indicate, in fact, that, according to defined criteria and weight coefficients, the sequence of types of renewable energy sources is absolutely identical regardless of the stakeholder. The sequence of priorities in the application of renewable energy sources for the production of electricity goes as follows:

  1. Biomass

  2. Mini hydros

  3. Geothermal

  4. Wind energy

  5. Solar energy

Further activities of all stakeholders should be given to mini hydros and biomass, since they have the best relation toward the aforementioned criteria.

According to presented model, potentials of all the mentioned types of renewable energy sources are capable for achieving its goals, with the limitation that wind and geothermal energy would have, according to such a premise, a 96.82% usage, which is not a convenient circumstance, while biomass would have an 8.61% usage and mini hydros 24.20%.

The general conclusion is that the state as a stakeholder should focus its activities regarding the production of electricity from renewable energy sources on biomass and mini hydros, since, according to listed hypotheses, defined criteria and the application of the mathematical model, they proved to be the best solution. The same goes for investors and local community as stakeholders.

Methodology use in this chapter is taken into account the criteria and stakeholders which where possible to use according to the official available data. The final number of stakolders and criteria are endless and just make calculation model more comprehensive.

References

  1. 1. Edward Freeman, R. Univesity of Virginia. Faculty & Research. The Faculty Directory [Internet]. Available from: http://www.darden.virginia.edu/faculty-research/directory/ r-edward-freeman/
  2. 2. Radna Grupa.Ministarstvo energetike rudarstva i zastite zivotne sredine. Nacionalni akcioni plan za primenu obnovljivih izvora energije [Internet]. June 2013. Available from: http://www.mre.gov.rs/dokumenta-efikasnost-izvori.php
  3. 3. Narodna Skupština Republike Srbije zakon o ratifikaciji. Zakon o ratifikaciji ugovora o osnivanju energetske zajednice i Republike Albanije, Rapublike Bugarske, Bosne i Hercegovine, Republike Hrvatske, Bivše Jugoslovenske Republike Makednoije, Republike Crne Gore, Rumunije, Republike Srbije, i privremene misije Ujedinjenih Nacija na Kosovu u skladu sa rezolucijom 1244 Saveta bezbednosti Ujedinjenih Nacija [Internet]. July 2006. Available from: http://www.parlament.gov.rs/narodna-skupština. 1.html
  4. 4. Zorana Mihajlovic. Mistarstvo energetike rudarstva i zastite zivotne sredine. Politika Republike Srbije u oblasti obnovljivih izvora energije [Internet]. December 2012. Available from: http://www.serbio.rs/item/102-politika-republike-srbije-u-oblasti-obnovljivih- izvora-energije
  5. 5. Milutin Čupić, Milija Suknović. Odlučivanje. 6th ed. Beograd: Fakultet organizacionih Nauka, Univerziteta u Beogradu; 2010.
  6. 6. Available from: http://www.businessdictionary.com/definition/stakeholder-value-approach.html
  7. 7. T. Tsoutsos T, Drandaki M, Frantzeskaki N, Iosifidis E, Kiosses I. Sustainable energy planning by using multi-criteria analysis application in the island of Crete. Energy Policy. 2009;37(2009):1587–1600.

Notes

  • Taken from introduction of document NAPOIE, Ministarstvo energetike, razvoja i zaštite životne sredine, strana 18, Beograd 2013 [2].
  • Full name "Law on Ratification of the Treaty Establishing Energy Community between the European Community and the Republic of Albania, Republic of Bulgaria, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Republic of Croatia, Former Yugoslav Republic of Macedonia, Republic of Montenegro, Romania, Republic of Serbia and United Nations Interim Administration Mission on Kosovo in compliance with the Resolution 1244 of the UN Security Council" ("Službeni glasnik RS", no. 62/06).
  • R. Edward Freeman. The stakeholder theory is a theory of organizational management and business ethics that addresses morals and values in managing an organization [1].
  • Theoretical overview of the PROMEHTEE method is described in brief according to the "Odlučivanje", Milutin Čupić, Milija Suknović, Fakultet organizacionih nauka, Beograd 2010. All general theoretical formulas, functions and graphs are taken from Ref. [5].
  • http://www.businessdictionary.com/definition/stakeholder-value-approach.html.
  • This research paper gave initial idea for this chapter as well as for stakeholders and used criteria [6, 7].

Written By

Dejan Jovanovic and Ivan Pribicevic

Submitted: 22 October 2016 Reviewed: 06 February 2017 Published: 07 June 2017